Whoever has glanced through the pages of any text-book on Mercantile Law will hardly deny that Contract is the handmaid if not actually the child of Trade. Merchants and bankers must have what soldiers and farmers seldom need, the means of making and enforcing various agreements with ease and certainty. Thus, turning to the special case before us, we should expect to find that when Rome was in her infancy and when her free inhabitants busied themselves chiefly with tillage and with petty warfare, their rules of sale, loan, suretyship, were few and clumsy. Villages do not contain lawyers, and even in towns hucksters do not employ them. 'Poverty of Contract was in fact a striking feature of the early Roman Law, and can be readily understood in the light of the rule just stated. The explanation given by Sir Henry Maine is doubtless true, but does not seem altogether adequate. He points out' that the Roman house- hold consisted of many families under the rule of a ' Ancient Law, p. 312. B. E. 1 Digitized by Microsoft® 2 INTRODUCTION. paternal autocrat, so that few freemen had what we should call legal capacity, and consequently there arose few occasions for Contract. This may indeed account for the non-existence of Agency, but not for that of all other contractual forms. For if the households had been trading instead of farming corporations, they must necessarily have been more richly provided in this respect. The fact that their commerce was trivial, if it existed at all, alone accounts completely for the insignificance of Con- tract in their early Law. The origin of Contract as a feature of social life was therefore simultaneous with the birth of Trade and requires no further explanation. It is with the origin and history of its individual forms that the following pages have to deal. As Roman civilization progresses we find Commerce extending and Contract growing steadily to be more complex and more flexible. Before the end of the Roman Republic the rudimentary modes of agreement which sufficed for the requirements of a semi-barbarous people have been almost wholly transformed into the elaborate system of Contract preserved for us in the fragments of the Antonine jurists. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER I. THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS. At the most remote period concerning which statements of reasonable accuracy can be made, and which for convenience we may call the Regal Period, we can distinguish three ways of securing the fulfilment of a promise. The promise could be enforced either (1) by the person interested, or (2) by the gods, or (3) by the community. When however we speak of enforcement, we must not think of what is now called specific performance, a con- ception unknown to primitive Law. The only kind of enforcement then possible was to make punish- ment the alternative of performance. I. Self-help, the most obvious method of re- dress in a societj' just emerging from barbarism, was doubtless the most ancient protection to promises, since we find it to have been not only the mode by which the anger of the individual was expressed, but also one of the authorised means employed by the gods or the community to signify their displeasure. This rough form of justice fell within the domain of Law in the sense that the law allowed it, and even 1 2 Digitized by Microsoft® 4 THE EEGAL PERIOD : EARLY AGREEMENTS. encouraged men to punish the delinquent, whenever religion or custom had been violated. But as people grew more civilized and the nation larger, sdf-help must have proved a difficult and therefore inade- quate remedy. Accordingly its scope was by degrees narrowed, and at last with the introduction of surer methods it became wholly obsolete. II. Eeligious Law, as administered by the priests, the representatives of the gods, was another powerful agency for the support of promises. A violation of Fides, the sacred bond formed between the parties to an agreement, was an act of impiety which laid a burden on the conscience of the delin- quent and may even have entailed religious disabili- ties. Fides was of the essence of every compact, but there were certain cases in which its violation was punished with exceptional severity. If an agreement had been solemnly made in the presence of the gods, its breach was punishable as an act of gross sacrilege. III. The third agency for the protection of promises was legal in our sense of the word. It consisted of penalties imposed upon bad faith by the laws of the nation, the rules of the gens, or the by-laws of the guild to which the delinquent belonged. What the sanction was in each case we are left to conjecture. It may have been public disgrace, or exclusion from the guild, or the paying of a fine. And as some promises might be strength- ened by an appeal to the gods, so might others by an invocation of the people as witnesses. Agreements then might be of three kinds corre- Digitized by Microsoft® EARLY PACTA. 5 spending to the three kinds of sanction. They might consist of (1) an entirely formless compact, (2) a solemn appeal to the gods, or (3) a solemn appeal to the people. I. A formless compact is called pactum in the language of the twelve Tables. It was merely a distinct understanding between parties who trusted to each other's word, and in the infancy of Law it must have been the kind of agreement most generally used in the ordinary business of life. Such agreements are doubtless the oldest of all, since it is almost impossible to conceive of a time when men did not barter acts and promises as freely as they bartered goods and without the accompani- ment of any ceremony. Compacts of this sort were protected by the universal respect for Fides, and their violation may perhaps have been visited with penalties by the guild or by the gens. But intensely religious as the early Romans were, there must have been cases in which conscience was too weak a barrier against fraud, and slight penalties were ineffectual. Fear of the gods had to be reinforced by the fear of man, and self-help was the remedy which naturally suggested itself. In the twelve Tables pactum appears in a negative shape, as a compact by performing which retaliation or a law-suit could be avoided ^ If this compact was broken the offended party pursued his remedy. Similarly where a positive pactum was violated, the injured person must have had the option of chastising 1 Gell. XX. 1. 14. Auct. ad Her. ii. 13. 20. Digitized by Microsoft® 6 THE BEGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS. the delinquent. His revenge might take the form of personal violence, seizure of the other's goods, or the retention of a pawn already in his possession. He could choose his own mode of punishment, but if his adversary proved too strong for him, he doubtless had to go unavenged ; whereas if the broken agree- ment belonged to either of the other classes, the injured party had the whole support of the priesthood or the community at his back, and thus was certain of obtaining satisfaction. It is therefore plain that though formless agreements contained the germ of Contract, they could not have produced a true law of Contract, because by their very nature they lacked binding force. Their sanction depended on the caprice of individuals, whereas the essence of Contract is that the breach of an agreement is punishable in a particular way. A further element was needed, and this was supplied by the invocation of higher powers. II. At what period the fashion was introduced of confirming promises by an appeal to the gods it would be idle to guess. Originally, it seems, the plain meaning of such appeals was alone con- sidered, and their form was of no importance. But under the influence of custom or of the priest- hood, they assumed by degrees a formal character, and it is thus that we find them in our earliest authorities. Since Eeligion and Law were both at first the monopoly of the priestly order, and since the religious forms of promise have their counterpart in the customs of Greece and other primitive peoples, Digitized by Microsoft® PUBLIC AGREEMENTS. 7 whereas the secular forms are peculiarly RomanS the religious forms are evidently the older, and formal contract has therefore had a religious origin. Fides being a divine thing, the most natural means of confirming a promise was to place it under divine protection. This could be accomplished in two ways, by iusiurandum or by sponsio, each of which was a solemn declaration placing the promise or agreement under the guardianship of the gods. Each of these forms has a curious history, and as they are the earliest specimens of true Contract, we may discuss them in the next chapter. III. Another method, and one peculiar to the Romans, which naturally suggested itself for the protection of agreements, was to perform the whole transaction in view of the people. Publicity ensured the fairness of the agreement, and placed its ex- istence beyond dispute. If the transaction was essentially a public matter, such as the official sale of public lauds, or the giving out of public contracts, no formality seems ever to have been required, so that even a formless agreement was in that case binding. The same validity could be secured for private contracts by having them publicly witnessed, and, the nexuTn was but one application of this principle. In testamentary Law it seems probable that the public will in comitiis calatis was also formless, whereas in private the testator could only give effect to his will by formally saying to his fellow-citizens " testimonium, mihi perhibetote." Thus the two elements which turned a bare 1 See p. 22. Digitized by Microsoft® 8 THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS. agreement into a contract were religion and publicity. The naked agreements (pacta) need not concern us, since, their validity as contracts never received complete recognition. But it will be the object of the following pages to show how agreements grew into contracts by being invested with a religious or public dignity, and to trace the subsequent process by which this outward clothing was slowly cast ofif. Formalism was the only means by which Contract could have risen to an established position, but when that position was fully attained we shall find Contract discarding forms and returning to the state of bare agreement from which it had sprung. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER II. CONTRACTS OF THE EEGAL PERIOD. Art. 1. IvsiVRANDVM is derived by some from louisiurandum^, which merely indicates that Jupiter was the god by whom men generally swore. To make an oath was to call upon some god to witness the integrity of the swearer, and to punish him if he swerved from it. This appears from the wording of the oath inLivy^ where Scipio says: "Si sciens /alio, turn me, luppiter optime maxime, domum familiam remque meam pessimo leto afficias," and from the oath upon the luppiter lapis given by Polybius and Paulus Diaconus, where a man throws down a flint and says : " Si sciens folio, turn me Dispiter saliia urbe arceque bonis eiiciat, uti ego hunc lapidem." A promise accompanied by an oath was simply a unilateral contract under religious sanction. And it would seem that the oath was in fact used for purposes of contract. Cicero remarks^ that the oath was proved by the language of the XII Tables to have been in former times the most binding form of promise ; and since an oath was still morally binding 1 Of. Apul. de deo Socr. 5. = xxii. 53. 3 Off. III. 31. 111. Digitized by Microsoft® 10 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. in the time of Cicero, though it had then no legal force, the point of his remark must be that in earlier times the oath was legally binding also. From Dionysius we know that the altar of Hercules (called Ara Maxima) was a place at which solemn compacts (a-vvOrJKai) were often made', while Plautus and Cicero inform us that such compacts were solemnized by grasping the altar and taking an oath''- It would seem probable that the gods were consulted by the taking of auspices before an oath was made. Cicero says that even in private affairs the ancients used to take no step without asking the advice of the gods*; and we may safely conjecture that whenever a god was called upon to witness a solemn proniise, he was first enquired of, so that he might have the option of refusing his assent by giving unfavourable auspices. The terms of the oath were known as concepta uerba, at least in the later Republic, and like the other forms of the period they were strictly construed*. Periuriwm did not mean then, as now, false swearing. It meant the breach of an oath', the commission of any act at variance with the uerba concepta'^. There is some dispute as to what were the exact consequences of such a breach. Voigt' thinks that it merely entailed excommunication from religious rites, but Danz^ is clearly right in maintaining that its consequences in early times were far more serious ; 1 Dion. 1. 40. 2 piaut. Rud. 5. 2. 49. Cic. Flace. 36. 90. 3 Biv. 1. 16. 28. " Seru. ad Aen. 12. 13. " i.e. sciens fallere, Plin. Paneg.d'i. Seneca, Ben. iii. 37. 4. 8 Off. III. 29. 108. ' lus Nat. in. 229. 8 j{g„i. ^(j_ „_ g 149 Digitized by Microsoft® EFFECTS OF IVSIVSAJSfDVM. 11 they amounted in fact to complete outlawry. Cicero says that the sacratae leges of the ancients confirmed the validity of oaths. Now a sacrata lex was one which declared the transgressor to be sacer (i.e. a victim devoted) to some particular god^ and sacer in the so-called laws of Seruius Tullius^ and in the XII Tables' was the epithet of condem- nation applied to the undutiful child and the unrighteous patron. So likewise it seems highly probable that the breaker of an oath became sacer, and that his punishment, as Cicero hints'*, was usually death. The formula of an oath given by Polybius" is more comprehensive than that given by Paulus Diaconus^ for in it the swearer prays that, if he should transgress, he may forfeit not only the religious but also the civil rights of his countrymen. This shows that the oath-breaker was an utter outcast; in fact, as the gods could not always execute vengeance in person, what they did was to withdraw their protection from the offender and leave him to the punishment of his fellow-men'. The drawbacks to this method of contract were the same as those of the old English Law, which made hanging the penalty for a slight theft ; the penalty was likely to be out of all proportion to the injury inflicted by a breach of the promise. So awful indeed was it, that no promise of an ordinary kind could well be given in such a dangerous form, and consequently the oath was not available for the 1 Festus, p. 318, s.u. sacratae. - Fest. p. 230, s.u. plorare. » Seru. ad Aen. 6. 609. ^ Leg. ii. 9. 22. ^ ni. 25. 5 p. 114, s.u. lapideni. ' Liu. v. 11. 16. Digitized by Microsoft® 12 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. common affairs of daily life. The use of the oath therefore disappeared with the rise of other forms of binding agreement, the severity of whose remedies was proportionate to the rights which had been violated; while at the same time the breaking of an oath came to be considered as a moral, instead of a legal, offence, and by the end of the Republic entailed nothing more serious than disgrace (dedecus). In one instance only did the legal force of the oath survive. As late as the days of Justinian, the services due to patrons by their freedmen were still promised under oath'. But the penalty for the neglect of those services had changed with the development of the law. At and before the time of the XII Tables, the freedman who neglected his patron, like the patron who injured his freedman'', no doubt became sacer, and was an outlaw fleeing for his life, as we are told by Dionysius'. But in classical times the heavy religious penalty had disappeared, and the iurisiurandi ohligatio was en- forced by a special praetorian action, the actio operarum*. By the time of Ulpian the effects of the iurata operarum promissio seem indeed to have been identical with those of the operarum stipu- lation, though the forms of the two were still quite distinct. We may then summarise as follows our knowledge as to this primitive mode of contract : The form was a verbal declaration on the part of the promisor, couched in a solemn and carefully 1 38 Dig. 1. 7. = Seru. ad Aen. 6. 609. s n, iq. * 38 Big. 1. 2 and 7. = of. 33 Dig, 1. 10. Digitized by Microsoft® THE EARLY SP0N8I0. 13 worded^ formula (concepta uerba), wherein he called upon the gods (testari deosY, to behold his good faith and to punish him for a breach of it. The sanction was the withdrawal of divine protection, so that the delinquent was exposed to death at the hand of any man who chose to slay him. The mode of release, if any, does not appear. In classical times it was the acceptilatio^, but this was clearly anomalous and resulted from the similar juristic treatment of operae promissae and operae iuratae. Art. 2. Sponsio. Though the point is contested by high authority, yet it scarcely admits of a doubt that there existed from very early times another form, known as spon^io, by which agreements could be made under religious sanction. This method, as Danz has pointed out, was originally connected with the preceding one. It was derived from the stern and solemn compact made under an oath to the gods. But Danz goes too far when he identifies the two, and states that sponsio was but another name for the sworn promise^. The stages through which the sponsio seems to have passed tell a different story. The word is closely connected with (Tirovhrj, a-rrevSeiv, and hence originally meant a pouring out of wine'*, quite distinct from the con- vivial Xot^T) or lihatio^, so that " libation " is not its proper equivalent. The other derivation given by 1 38 Dig. 1. 7, fr. 3. ^ Plaut. Rud. 5. 2. 52. 5 46 Dig. 4. 13. '' Danz, Sacr. Schutz, p. 105. 5 Featus-p. 329 s.u. spondere. ^ Leist, Greco-It. B. G. p. 464, note o. Digitized by Microsoft® 14 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. Varro' and Verrius^ from spons, the will, whence according to Girtanner' spmsio must have meant a declaration of the will, savours somewhat too strongly of classical etymology. I. This pouring out of wine, as Leist* has ■ shown, was in the Homeric age a constant accom- paniment to the conclusion of a sworn compact of alliance (opKia iriaTo) between friendly nations. The sacrificial wine seems originally to have added force to the oath by symbolising the blood which would be spilt if the gods were insulted by a breach of that oath. In this then its original form sponsio was nothing more than an accessory piece of cere- monial. II. The second stage was brought about by the omission of the oath and by the use of wine-pouring alone as the principal ceremony in making less important agreements of a private nature. In the Indian Sutras for instance a sacrifice of wine is customary at betrothals ^ and comparison shows that the marriage ceremonies of the Romans, in connec- tion with which we find sponsio and sponsalia applied to the betrothal and sponsa to the bride °, were very like those of other Aryan communities'. We may therefore clearly infer that at Rome also there was a time when the pouring out of wine was a part of the marriage-contract; and thus our derivation of the word receives independent confirmation. III. In the third and last stage sponsio meant ^ L. L. VI. 7. 69. ° Festus, s. u. spotidere. ' Stip. p. 84. •* Greco-It. B. G. § 60. = Leist, Alt-Ar. I. Civ. p. 443. » Gell. IV. 4. Varro, L. L. vi. 7. 70. ' Leist, loc. cit. Digitized by Microsoft® PECULIARITIES OF SPONSIO. 15 nothing more than a particular form of promise, and it is easy to see how this came about. At first the verbal promise took its name from the ceremony of wine-pouring which gave to it binding force ; but in course of time this ceremony was left out as taken for granted, and then the promise alone, provided words of style were correctly used, still retained its old uses and its old name. Sponsio from being a ceremonial act became a form of words. Such was the final stage of its development. The importance attached to the use of the words spondesne ?, spondeo in preference to all others' thus becomes clear. Spondesne ? spondeo originally meant " Do you promise by the sacrifice of wine ? " "I do so promise," just as we say, "I give you my oath," when we do not dream of actually taking one. Another peculiarity of sponsio, noticed though not explained by Gaius^, was the fact that it could be used in one exceptional case to make a binding agreement between Romans and aliens, namely, at the conclusion of a treaty. Gains expresses surprise at this exception. But if, as above stated, a sacrifice of pure wine ((nrovBal aKprjToi) was one of the early formalities of an international compact (opKia iria-Ta), it was natural that the word spo'ndeo should survive on such occasions, even after the oath and the wine- pouring had long since vanished. Sponsio being then a religious act and subse- quently a religious formula, its sanctity was doubtless protected by the pontiffs with suitable penalties. What these penalties were we cannot hope to know, 1 Gai. HI. 93. ^ m. 94. Digitized by Microsoft® 16 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. though clearly they were the forerunners of the penal sponsio tertiae partis of the later procedure. Varro^ informs us that, besides being used at be- trothals the sponsio was employed in money (pecunia) transactions. If pecunia includes more than money we may well suppose that cattle and other forms of property, which could be designated by number and not by weight, were capable of being promised in this manner. Indeed it is by no means unlikely^ that nesBum was at one time the proper form for a loan of money by weight, while sponsio was the proper form for a loan of coined money (pecunia numerata). The making of a sponsio for a sum of money was at all events the distinguishing feature of the actio per sponsionem, and though we cannot now enter upon the disputed history of that action, its antiquity will hardly be denied. The account here given of the origin and early history of the sponsio is so different from the views taken by many excellent authorities that we must examine their theories in order to see why they appear untenable. One great class of commentators have held that the sponsio is not a primitive institu- tion, but was introduced at a date subsequeat to the XII Tables. The adherents of this theory are afraid of admitting the existence, at so early a period, of a form of contract so convenient and flexible as the sponsio, and they also attach great weight to the fact that no mention of sponsio occurs in our fragments of the XII Tables. While it would doubtless be an anachronism to ascribe to the early 1 L. L. VI. 7. 70. 2 Karsten, Stip. p. 42. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF SP0N810. 17 sponsio the actionability and breadth of scope which it had in later times, still it may very well have been sanctioned by religious law, in ways of which nothing can be known unless the pontifical Com- mentaries of Papirius' should some day be discovered. As to the silence of the XII Tables on this subject, we are told by Pomponius that they were intended to define and reform the law rather than to serve as a comprehensive code". Therefore they may well have passed over a subject like sponsio which was already regulated by the priesthood. Or, if they did mention it, their provisions on the subject may have been lost, like the provisions as to iusiurandmn, which we know of only through a casual remark of Cicero's '>- The early date here attributed to the sponsio cannot therefore be disproved by any such negative evidence. Let us see how the case stands with regard to the question of origin. (a) The theory best known in England, owing to its support by Sir H. Maine, is that sponsio was a simplified form of nexum, in which the ceremonial had fallen away and the nuncupatio had alone been left^. This explanation is now so utterly obsolete that it is not worth refuting, especially since Mr Hunter's exhaustive criticism^ One fact which in itself is utterly fatal to such a theory is that the nuncupatio was an assertion requiring no reply". 1 Dion. III. 3(5. ^ 1 Dig- 2. 2. 4. 3 Off. m. 31. 111. * Maine, Anc. Law, p. 326. 5 Hunter, Bovian Law, p. 385. " Gai. ii. 24. B. E. 2 Digitized by Microsoft® 18 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. whereas the essential thing about the sponsio was a question coupled with an answer. (6) Voigt follows Girtanner in maintaining that spondere signified originally " to declare- one's will," and he vaguely ascribes the use of sponsiones in the making of agreements to an ancient custom existing at Rome as well as in Latium'. He agrees with the view here expressed that the sponsio was known prior to the XII Tables, but thinks that before the XII Tables it was neither a contract (which is strictly true if by contract we mean an agreement enforceable by action), nor an act in the law, and that its use as a contract began in the fourth century as a result of Latin influenced In another place' he expresses the opinion that its introduction as a contract was due to legislation, and most probably to the Lex Silia. The objections to ■ this view are (1) that the etymology is probably wrong, and (2) that the inference drawn as to the original meaning of spondere involves us in serious diflSculties. An expression of the will can be made by a formless declaration as well as by a formal one. And if a formless agreement be a sponsio, as it must be if sponsio means any declaration of the will, how are we to explain the formal importance attaching to the use of the particular words '' spon- desne ? spondeo." (3) This view ignores the religious nature of the sponsio, which I have endeavoured to establish, and (4) it forgets that sponsio, being part of the marriage ceremonial, one of the first subjects 1 Bom. EG. 1. p. 42. ' lb. p. 43. 3 lus Nat. §§ 33-4. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF SPONSIO. 19 to be regulated by the laws of Romulus \ is most probably one of the oldest Roman institutions. Again (5), as Esmarch has observed^ the legislative origin of the sponsio is a very rash hypothesis. We only know that the Lex Silia introduced an improved procedure for matters which were already actionable, and had a new formal contract been created by such a definite act we should almost certainly have been informed of this by the classical writers. (c) Danz also derives sponsio from spans, the vvill; but he takes spondere to mean sua sponte iurare, and thinks that the original sponsio was exactly the same as iusiurandum, i.e. nothing more than an oath of a particular kind^. His chief argu- ment for this view is to be found in Paulus Diaconus, who gives consponsor = coniurator. But why need we suppose that Paulus meant more than to give a synonym ? in which case it by no means follows that spondere = iurare. For such a statement as that we have absolutely no authority. Moreover, as we saw above, iusiurandum was a one-sided declaration on the part of the promisor only. How then could the sponsio, consisting as it did of question and answer, have sprung from such a source ? especially since the iusiurandum, though no longer armed with a legal sanction, was still used as late as the days of Plautus alongside of the sponsio and in complete contrast to it ? {d) Girtanner, in his reply to the "Sacrale Schutz" of Danz^, maintains that sponsio had nothing 1 Dion. n. 25. ^ ^. y_ far q. u. R. W. ii. 516. ^ Sacr. Schutz, p. 149. *' Ueber die Sponsio, p. 4 ft. 2—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 20 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. to do with an oath, but was a simple declaration of the individual will, and that stipulatio had its origin in the respect paid to Fides. This view however is even less supported by evideiice than that of Danz'. Arguing again from analogy Girtanner thinks that, as the Roman people regulated its affairs by expressing its will publicly in the Comitia, so we may conjecture that individuals could validly express their will in private affairs, in other words could make a binding sponsio. But this, as well as being a wrong analogy, is a misapprehension of a leading principle of early Law. For, as we have seen, no agreement resting simply upon the will of the parties (i.e. pactwn) was valid without some outward stamp being affixed to it, in the shape of approval expressed by the gods or by the people. In the language of the more modem law, we may say that such approval, tacit or explicit, religious or secular, was the original caiisa ciuilis which dis- tinguished contractus from pactiones. Now a popular vote in the Comitia bore the stamp of public approval as plainly as did the nexum. But the sponsio, requiring no witnesses, was clearly not endorsed by the people ; therefore the endorsement which it needed in order to become a contractus iuris ciuilis must have been of a religious nature, and that such was the case appears plainly if we admit that sponsio originated in a religious cere- monial such as I have described. To recapitulate the view here given, we mav conclude that sponsio was a primordial institution 1 See Windsoheid, K. Y. fiir G. u. R. W. i. 291. Digitized by Microsoft® GROWTH OP SPONSION 21 of the Roman and Latin peoples, which grew into its later form through three stages, (a) It was originally a sacrifice of wine annexed to a solemn compact of alliance or of peace made under an oath to the gods. (b) Next it became a sacrifice used as an appeal to the gods in compacts not jtnade under oath such as betrothals. Just as iusiurandum for many purposes was sufficient without the pouring out of wine, so for other purposes sponsio came to be sufficient without the oath, (c) Lastly it became a verbal formula, expressed in language implying the accompaniment of a wine-sacrifice, but at the making of which no sacrifice was ever actually performed. In this final stage, which continued as late as the days of Justi- nian, Its form was a question put by the promisee, and an answer given by the promisor, each using the verb spondere. " Filiam mihi spondesne ? " " Spondeo." " Centum dari spondes ? " " Spondeo." Throughout its history this was a form which Roman citizens alone could use, in which fact we clearly see religious exclusiveness and a further proof of religious origin. Why they used question and answer rather than plain statement is a minor point the origin of which no theory has yet accounted for. The most plausible conjecture seems to be that the recapitulation by the promisee was intended to secure the complete understanding by the promisor of the exact nature of his promise. Its sanction in the early period of which we are treating was doubtless imposed by the priests, but owing to our almost complete ignorance of the Digitized by Microsoft® 22 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. pontifical law we cannot tell what that sanction was. Having now examined the ways in which an agreement could be made binding under religious sanction, let us see how binding agreements could be made with the approval of the community. There is reason to believe that this secular class of contracts is less ancient than the religious class, because nexum, and mancipium were peculiar to the Romans, whereas traces of iusiurandum and sponsio are found, as Leist has shown, in other Aryan civilizations'. Art. 3. NEXVM. There is no more disputed sub- ject in the whole history of Roman Law than the origin and development of this one contract. Yet the facts are simple, and though we cannot be sure that every detail is accurate, we have enough information to see clearly what the transaction was like as a whole. We know that it was a negotium per aes et libram, a weighing of raw copper or other commodity measured by weight in the presence of witnesses^; that the commodity so weighed was a loan' ; and that default in the repayment of a loan thus made exposed the borrower to bondage* and savage punishment at the hands of the lender. We know also that it existed as a loan before the XII Tables, for it is mentioned in them as something quite different from mancipivjn^. To assert, as Bech- mann does, that since nexum included conveyance as 1 Alt Ar. I. Civ. !•" Abt. pp. 435-443. 2 Gai. III. 173. 3 Mucins in Varro, L. L. 7. 105. " Varro, L. L. vi. 5. 5 Clark, B. E. L. § 22. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF NEXVM. 23 well as loan " mancipiuvique " must therefore be an interpolation into the text of the XII Tables S is an arbitrary and unnecessary conjecture. The etymology of nexum and of mancipium shows that they were distinct conceptions. Mancipium implies the transfer of manus, ownership ; nexum implies the making of a bond {cf. nectere, to bind), the precise equivalent of obligatio in the later law. It is true that both nexum and mancipium required the use of copper and scales, to measure in one case the price, in the other the amount of the loan. But this coincidence by no means proves that the two transactions were identical. A modem deed is used both for leases and for conveyances of real property, yet that would be a strange argument to prove that a lease and a conveyance were originally the same thing. Here however we are met by a difficulty. If, as some hold " and as I have tried to prove, we must regard mancipium as an institution of prehistoric times distinct from the purely contractual nexum, how are we to explain the fact that nexum is used by Cicero' and by other classical writers' as equi- valent to mancipium, or as a general term signifying omne quod per aes et libram geritur, whether a loan, a will, or a conveyance ? Now first we must notice the fact that nexum had at any rate not always been synonymous with mancipium, for if it had been so, there could have been no doubt in the minds of 1 Kauf, p. 130. ^ Mommsen, Hint. 1. 11. p. 162 n. 3 ad Fam. 7. 30; de Or. 3. 40; Top. 5. 28; Farad. 5. 1. 35.; pro Mur. 2. * Boethius lib. 3 ad Top. 5. 28 ; Gallua Aelius in Festus, s.u. nexum ; Manilius in Varro, L. L. 7. 105. Digitized by Microsoft® 24 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. Scaeuola and Varro that a res nexa was the same thing as a res mandpata. This Scaeuola and Varro both deny, and we must remember that Mucins Scaeuola was the Papinian of his day. ManiUus* on the other hand, struck perhaps by the likeness in form of the obsolete nexum to other still existing iwgotia per aes et Ubram, seems to have made nexum into a generic term for this whole class of trans- actions. In this he was followed by Gallus Aelius'. The new and wider meaning, given by them to that which was a technical term at the period of the XII Tables, apparently became general in literature, partly for the very reason that nexum no longer had an actual existence, partly because neon liberatio, the old release of nexum, had been adopted by custom as the proper form of release in matters which had nothing to do with the original nexum, namely in the release of judgment-debts and of legacies per damnationem^. One pecuUarity men- tioned by Gains in the release of such legacies seems altogether fatal to the theory that mandpium was but a species of the genus nexum. Gains says that nexi liberatio could be used only for legacies of things measured by weight. Such things were the sole objects of the true nexum, whereas res mancijri included land and cattle. Therefore if mandpivm were only a species of nexum we should certainly find nexi liberatio applying to legacies of res mandpi, but this, as Gaius shows, was not the case. The view that nexum was the parent gestum per 1 Varro, L. L. vii. 105. ' Festus, p. 165, s. u. nexum. s Gai. III. 173-5. Digitized by Microsoft® NBXVM DISTINCT FROM MANCIPIVM. 25 aes et libram, and that mancipium was the name given later to one particular form of nexum, is worth examining at some length, because it is widely accepted S and because it fundamentally affects our opinion concerning the early history of an important contract. Bechmann^ thinks it more reasonable to suppose that nexum narrowed from a general to a specific conception. But it is scarcely conceivable that nexum should have had the vague generic meaning of quodcumque per aes et libram geritur^ when it was still a living mode of contract, and the technical meaning of obligatio per aes et libram when such a contractual form no longer existed. What seems far more likely is that nexum had a technical meaning until it ceased to be practised subsequently to the Lex Poetilia, and that its loose meaning was introduced in the later Republic, partly to denote the binding force of any contract*, partly as a convenient expression for any transaction per aes et libram'^. Even in Cicero we find the word nexum used chiefly with a view to elegance of style" in places where mandpatio would have been a clumsy word and where' there could be no doubt as to the real meaning. But when Cicero is writing history, he uses nexum in its old technical sense and actually tells us that it had become obsolete'. 1 See Beohmann, Kauf, i. p. 130 ; Clark, E. R. L. § 22. 2 lb. p. 131. " Varro, I. c. — Pestus, s.u. nexum. ■» Cf. ''nexu uenditi " in Ulpian, 12 Dig. 6. 26. 7. 5 Cio. de Or. iii. 40. 159. 6 Har. Eesp. vii. 14; ad Fam. vii. 30. 2; Top. 5. 28. ' As in pro Mur. 2; Parad. v. 1. 35. 8 de Rep. 2. 34 and cf. Liu. viii. 28. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 26 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. Rejecting then as untenable the notion that neseum denoted a variety of transactions, let us see how it originated. The most obvious way of lending com or copper or any <other ponderable commodity, was to weigh it out to the borrower, who would naturally at the same time specify by word of mouth the terms on which he accepted the loan. In order to make the transaction binding, an obvious precaution would be to call in witnesses, or if the transaction took place, as it most likely would, in the market-place, the mere publicity of the loan would be enough. Thus it was, we may believe, that a nexum was originally made. It was a formless agreement necessarily accompanied by the act of weighing and made under public super- vision. It dealt only with commodities which could be measured with the scales and weights, and did not recognize the distinction between res mancipi and res nee mancipi, — a strong argument that neoeum and mancipium were, as above said, totally distinct affairs. Its sanction lay in the acts of violence which the creditor might see fit to commit against the debtor, if payment was not performed according to the terms of his agreement. Personal violence was regulated by the XII Tables, in the rules of manus iniectio, but before that time it is safe to conjecture that any form of retaliation against the person or property of the debtor was freely allowed. The fixing of the number of witnesses at five', which we find also in mancipium, is the only modification of nexum that we know of prior to ' Gai. III. 174. Digitized by Microsoft® FUNCTION OF NEXAL WITNESSES. 27 the XII Tables. Bekker^ suggests that this change was one of the reforms of Seruius Tullius, and that the five witnesses, by representing the five classes of the Servian census, personified the whole people. This is a mere conjecture, but a very plausible one. For we are told by Dionysius^ that Seruius made fifty enactments on the subject of Contract and Crime, and in another passage of the same author', we find an analogous case of a law which forbade the exposure of a child except with the approval of five ■ witnesses. But here a question has been raised as to what the witnesses did. The correct answer, I believe, is that given by Bechmann*, who maintains that the witnesses approved the transaction as a whole, and vouched for its being properly and fairly performed. Huschke, on the other hand, claims that the function of the witnesses was to superintend the weighing of the copper, and that before the intro- duction of coined money some such public supervision was necessary in order to convert the raw copper into a lawful medium of exchange^. This view is part of Huschke's theory, that neosum had two marked peculiarities: (1) it was a legal act per- formed under public authority, and (2) it was the recognised mode of measuring out copper money by weight. The first part of Huschke's theory may be accepted without reserve, but the second part seems quite untenable. We have no evidence to show that neooum was confined to loans of money or of 1 Akt. I. 22 ff. 2 jy_ IS -J jj. 15. * Kauf, I. p. 90. ^ Nex-um, p. 16 ff. Digitized by Microsoft® 28 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. copper. Indeed we gather from a passage of Cicero that far, corn, may have been the earliest object of neooum', while Gains states that anything measurable by weight could be dealt with by nexi solutio'. No inference in favour of Huschke's theory can be drawn from the name negotium per aes et lihram, for this phrase obviously dates from the more recent times when the ceremony had only a formal signifi- cance, and when the aes {rauduscidum) was merely struck against the scales. If then we reject the second part of Huschke's theory, and admit, as , we certainly should, that nescum could deal with any ponderable commodity, it is evident that his whole view as to the function of the witnesses must collapse also. The very notion of turning copper from merchandise into legal tender is far too subtle to have ever occurred to the minds of the early Romans. As Bechmann* rightly remarks, the original object of the State in making coin was not to create an authorised medium of exchange, but simply to warrant the weight and fineness of the medium most generally used. The view of Huschke seems therefore a complete anachronism. There is also another interpretation of neivum radically different from the one here advocated, and formerly given by some authorities^ but which has few if any supporters among modern jurists. This view was founded upon a loosely expressed remark of Varro's in which nexus is defined as 1 Cio. de Leg. Agr. ii. 30. 83. ^ in. 175. » Xauf, i. p. 87. * See Sell, Soheurl, Niebuhr, Christiansen, Puohta, quoted in Danz, BSm. RG. ii. 25. Digitized by Microsoft® NEXVM A LOAN BY WEIGHT. 29 a freeman who gives himself into slavery for a debt which he owes\ The inference drawn from this remark was that the debtor's body, not the creditor's money, was the object of nexvm, and that a debtor who sold himself by mancipium as a pledge for the repayment of a loan was said to make a newum'K Such a theory does not however harmonize with the facts. The evidence is entirely opposed to it, for Varro's statement, as will be seen later on, admits of quite another meaning. Neither nexum nor Tnan- cipium is ever found practised by a man upon his own person. Nor could nexum have applied to a debtor's person, for the idea of treating a debtor like a res mmicipi or like a thing quod pundere numero C07istat, is absurd. Again, if neccu/m = mancipium, the conveyance of the debtor's body as a pledge must have taken effect as soon as the money was lent, therefore (1) by thus becoming nexus he must have been in mancipio long before a default could occur, which is too strange to be believed, and (2) being in mancipio he must have been capita deminutus^, which Quintilian expressly states that no nexal debtor ever was*. Clearly then mancipium was under no cir- cumstances a factor in nexum,. Thus it would seem that the theory which regards nexum as a loan of raw copper or other goods measurable by weight, is the one beset with fewest difficulties. Such goods correspond pretty nearly to what in the later law were called res fungihiles. 1 Varro, L. L. vii. 105 and see page 52. 2 nexum inire, Liu. vii. 19. 5. " Paul. Diao. p. 70, s. u. deminutus. * Decl. 311. Digitized by Microsoft® 30 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. The borrower was not required to return the very same thing, but an equal quantity of the same kind of thing. And this explains why neancm, the first genuine contract of the Eoman Law, should have received such ample protection. A tool or a beast of burden could be lent with but little risk, for either could be easily identified ; but the loan of corn or of metal would have been attended with very great risk, had not the law been careful to ensure the publicity of every such transaction. lusiurandum or sponsio might no doubt have been used for making loans, but they both lacked the great advantage of accurate measurement, which necmm owed to its public character. It was the presence of witnesses which raised neocum from a formless loan into a contract of loan. This general sketch of the original neooum is all that can be given with certainty. The details of the picture cannot be filled in, unless we draw upon our imagination. We do not know what verbal agreement passed between the borrower and the lender, though it is fairly certain that payment of interest on the loan might be made a part of the contract. We cannot even be quite sure whether the scale-holder (libripens) was an official, as some have suggested, or a mere assistants Our description of the contract may then be briefly recapitulated as follows: The form consisted of the weighing out and delivery to the borrower of goods measurable by weight, in the presence of witnesses, (five in number, ' See page 52. Digitized by Microsoft® EARLY FORM OF NEXVM. 31 probably since the time of Seruius Tullius), whose attendance ensured the proper performance of the ceremony. The ownership of the particular goods passed to the borrower, who was merely bound to return an equal quantity of the same kind of goods, but the terms of each contract were approximately fixed by a verbal agreement uttered at the time. The sanction consisted of the violent measures which the creditor might choose to take against a defaulting debtor. Before the XII Tables there .seems to have been no limit to the creditor's power of punishment. Any violence against the debtor was approved by custom and justified by the noto- riety of the transaction, so that self-help was more easily exercised and probably more severe in the case of nexum than in that of any other agreement. The release (neooi solutio) was a ceremony pre- cisely similar to that of the neocum itself, the amount of the loan being weighed and delivered to the lender, in presence of witnesses '. Art. 4. We have now examined three methods by which a binding promise could be made in the earliest period of the Roman Law. The next question which confronts us is whether there existed at that time any other method. The other forms of contract, besides those already described, which are found existing at the period of the XII Tables, were fiducia, lex mancipi, uadimoniv/m, and dotis dictio. Did any of these have their origin before this time ? Fiducia is doubtful, and lex mancipi, as we shall see, owed its existence to an important provision 1 Gai. III. 174. Digitized by Microsoft® 32 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. of that code. As to the origin of uadimonium, we cannot fee certain, but judging from a passage in Gellius* we are almost forced to the conclusion that uadimonium also was a creation of the XII Tables. Gellius speaks of " uades et subuades et XX V asses et taliones...omnisque ilia XII Tabularum antiquitas." We know that twenty-five asses was the fine imposed by the XII Tables for cutting down another man's tree, therefore it would seem from the context that uades had also been introduced by that code. The point cannot be settled, but since the XII Tables were at any rate the first enactments on the subject of which anything is known, we may discuss uadimonium in treating of the next period. The only contract of which the remote antiquity is beyond dispute is the dotis dictio. Art. 0. DOTIS DICTIO. Dionysius^ informs us that in the earliest times a dowry was given with daughters on their marriage, and that if the father could not afford this expense his clients were bound to contribute. Hence it is clear not only that dos existed from very early times, but that custom even in remote antiquity had fenced it about with strict rules. From Ulpian' we know that dos could be bestowed either by dotis dictio, dotis promissio, or dotis datio. The promissio was a promise by stipu- lation, and the datio was the transfer by mancipation or tradition of the property constituting the dowry ; so that these two are easy to understand. But dotis dictio is an obscure subject. It is diflBcult to know whence it acquired its binding force as a contract, 1 xTi. 10. 8. 2 II. 10. 3 Reg. vi. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO DOTIS DICTIO. 33 since in form it was unlike all other contracts with which we are acquainted. Its antiquity is evidenced not only by this peculiarity of form, but also by a passage in the Theodosian Code which speaks of dotis dictio as conforming with the ancient law'. An illustration occurs in Terence^ where the father says, "Dos, Pamphile, est decern talenta," and Pamphilus, the future son-in-law, replies, " Accipio " ; but we need not conclude that the transaction was always formal, for the above Code°, in permitting the use of any form, seems rather to be restating the old law than making a new enactment. A further peculiarity, stated by Ulpian* and by Gaius^ was that dotis dictio could be validly used only by the bride, by her father or cognates on the father's side, or by a debtor of the bride acting with her authority. Dictio is a significant word, for Ulpian'' distinguishes between dictum and promis- sum, the former, he says, being a mere statement, the latter a binding promise. This distinction should doubtless be applied in the present case, since dotis dictio and dotis promissio were clearly different. The following theories seem to be erroneous : (a) Von Meykow' holds that dictio was adopted as a form of promise instead of sponsio for this family affair of dos, in order not to hurt the feelings of the biide and of her kinsmen by appearing to question their bona fides. That theory would be a plausible explanation, if dictio could ever have meant a 1 C. Th. 3. 12. 3. 2 And. 5. 4. 48. ■' 3. 13. 4. * Reg. VI. 2. ^ Epit. ii. 9. 3. « 21 Dig. 1. 19. ' Diet. d. Rom. Brautg. p. 5 ff. B. E. 3 Digitized by Microsoft® 34 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. promise, but from what Ulpian says, this can hardly be admitted. (6) Bechmann^ again, connects dotis dictio with the ceremony otsponsio at the betrothal of a daughter. The dos, he thinks, was promised by a sponsio made at the betrothal, so that the peculiar form known as dotis dictio was originally nothing more than the specification of a dowry already promised. The dotis dictio would therefore have been at first a mere pactum adiectam, which was made actionable in later times, while still preserving its ancient form. The objection to this theory is that it lacks evidence : indeed the only passage (that of Terence) in which dotis dictio is presented to us with a context goes to show that this contract was in no way connected with the act of betrothal. (c) Another explanation is given by Czylharz^ i.e. that dotis dictio was a formal contract. His view is based on the scholia attached to the passage of Terence, which say of the bridegroom's answer : " ille nisi diodsset ' accipio ' dos non esset." Czylharz therefore looks upon the contract as an inverted stipulation. The offer of a promise was made by the promisor, and when accepted by the promisee became a contract. Though such a process is quite in harmony with modern notions of Contract, it would have been a complete anomaly at Rome. And we cannot believe that, if acceptance by the promisee had been a necessary part of the dotis dictio, we should not have been so informed by Gaius, when he has been so careful to impress 1 ESm. Dotalrecht. 2 Abt. p. 103. 2 Z. f. B. G. vn. 243. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORY OF DANZ. 35 upon US that the dotis dictio could be made nulla interrogatione praecedente. Thus the view of Czylharz besides being in itself improbable is almost entirely unsupported by evidence. Even the scholiast on Terence need not necessarily mean that " accipio " was an indispensable part of the trans- action. He may merely have meant that the bride- groom at this juncture could decline the proffered dos if he chose, and this interpretation is borne out by lulianus" and Marcellus^ who give formulae of dotis dictio without any words of acceptance. A satisfactory solution of the problem seems to have been found by Danz'. He looks upon dos as having been due from the father or male ascendants of the bride as an officium, pietatis*, and quotes passages from the classical writers in which they speak of refusing to dower a sister or a daughter as a most shameful thing'. The source of the obligation lay in this relationship to the bride, not in any binding effect of the dotis dictio itself. But in order that the obligation might be actionable its amount had to be fixed, and this was just what the dictio accomplished. It was an acknowledgment of the debt which custom had decreed that the bride's family must pay to the bridegroom. In this respect the dos was precisely analogous to the debt of service which a freedman owed as an officium to bis patron, and which he acknowledged by the iurata operarum promissio. The dos and the operae were both officia pietatis, but 1 23 Dig. 3. 44. ^ 23 Dig. 3. 59. ' Rom. BG. 1. 163. ^ See 23 Dig. 3. 2. ' piaut. Trin. 3. 2. 63 ; Cic. Quint. 31. 98. .3—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 36 CONTEACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. it became customary to specify their nature and their quantity. In the one case this was done by an oath, in the other by a simple declaration, and in both cases the law gave an action to protect these anomalous forms of agreement. What kind of action could be brought on a dotis dictio is not known. Voigt^ states it to have been an actio dictae dotis, for which he even gives the formula, but formula and action are alike purely conjectural. We can only infer that the dotis dictio was action- able since it constituted a valid contract. How or when this came to pass we cannot tell. A further advantage of Danz' theory, and one not mentioned by him, is that it explains the capacity of the three classes of persons by whom alone dotis dictio could be performed. (1) The father and male ascendants of the bride were bound to provide a dos under penalty of ignominia^ ; (2) the bride, if sui iuris, was bound to contribute to the support of her husband's household for exactly the same reason'; and (3) a debtor of the bride was bound to carry out her orders with respect to her assets in his posses- sion, and supposing her whole fortune to have con- sisted of a debt due to her, it is evident that a dotis dictio by the debtor was the only way in which this fortune could be settled as a dos at all. Thus the hypothesis that the dos was a debt morally due from the father of the bride, or from the bride herself, whenever a marriage took place, completely explains the curious limitation with 1 XII Taf. II. § 123. 2 24 Dig. 3. 1. 3 Cio. Top. i. 23. Digitized by Microsoft® FORM OF DOTIS DICTIO. 37 regard to the parties who could perform dotis dictio. The nature of the transaction may then be summarized as follows : Its form was an oral declaration on the part of (1) the bride's father or male cognates, (2) of the bride herself, or (3) of a debtor of the bride, setting forth the nature and amount of the property which he or she meant to bestow as dowry, and spoken in the presence of the bridegroom. Land as well as moveables could be settled in this manner'. No particular formula was necessary. The bridegroom might, if he liked, express himself satisfied with the dos so specified ; but his acceptance does not seem to have been an essential feature of the proceeding. Most probably he did not have to speak at all. Its sanction does not appear, though we may be sure that there was some action to compel perform- ance of the promise. This action, whatever it may have been, could of course be brought by the bride's husband against the maker of the dotis dictio. Perhaps in the earliest times the sanction was a purely religious one. Art. 6. Now that we have seen the various ways in which a binding contract could be made in the earliest period of Eoman history, we may con- sider briefly the general characteristics of that primi- tive contractual system. The first striking point is that all the contracts hitherto mentioned are unilateral : the promisor alone was bound, and he was not entitled, in virtue of the contract, to any counterperformance on the part of the promisee. 1 Gai. Ep. 3. 9. Digitized by Microsoft® 38 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD. The second point is that the consent of the parties was not sufficient to bind them. Over and above that consent the agreement between them was required to bear the stamp of popular or divine approval. Even in dotis dictio, as we have just seen, a simple declaration uttered by the promisor was invested with the force of a contract merely because the substance of that declaration was a transfer of property approved and required by public opinion. Thirdly we notice that the intention of the con- tracting parties was verbally expressed, but that the language employed was not originally of any impor- tance (except in the one case of sponsio), provided the intention was clearly conveyed. We must therefore modify the statement so commonly made that the earliest known contracts were couched in a particular form of words. For how did each of these particular forms originate and acquire the shape in which we afterwards find it ? By having long been used to express agreements which were binding though their language was informal, and by having thus gradually obtained a technical significance. Conse- quently the formal stage was not the earliest stage of Contract. The most primitive contract of all was not an agreement clothed with a form, but an agree- ment clothed with the approval of Church or State. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER III. THE TWELVE TABLES. Art. 1. The causes leading to the enactment of the great Reform Bill known as the XII Tables were chiefly social, and the indefinite state of the law was the grievance which called most loudly for a remedy. Contracts and conveyances were but little respected, the powers of the nexal creditor were sorely abused, and legal procedure in general was most uncertain. Yet more than all else the law of torts and crimes needed radical reform : so that though we possess but few actual fragments of the XII Tables we have enough to tell us that very little space was devoted to reforms in the law of Contract. This fact ought not to surprise us, knowing as we do that commerce was still in a very backward state. We hear nothing of any provision in the XII Tables with respect to sponsio, but we know from Cicero that iusiurandwn was recognised and enforced'. Botis dictio was not mentioned, so far as we can discover. A new form, the lex mancipi, 1 Off. HI, 31. 111.. Digitized by Microsoft® 40 THE TWELVE TABLES. was created by one provision of this code, though its creation was not apparently intended by the Decemvirs, but was rather the result of juristic interpretation. Vadimoniitm,, a contract which we have not yet examined, was either created or considerably modified by the XII Tables, and con- stituted the earliest form of suretyship. As the hard condition of nexal debtors was one of the evils which led most directly to the secession of the plebs and to the consequent enactment of the new code, we should naturally expect to find laws passed for their protection. Accordingly it is with nexum that the contractual clauses of the XII Tables are principally concerned. Art. 2. NEXVM. I. The first provision as to this contract was embodied in the famous words which Festus has transmitted to us: CVM nexym FACIET MANCIPIVMQVE VTI LINGVA NVNCVPASSIT ITA ivs ESTO^ This was equivalent to saying that the language used by the party making a nexum was to be strictly followed in determining what his rights and liabilities should be. The fact that such a declaratory law was needed discloses two features of the primitive nexum. We can see (1) that the act of weighing, not the words which accompanied that act, was the essence of the original transaction, so that the scales must have been used actually, and not symbolically as they were in later days : (2) that the terms of a nexal loan must often have been disobeyed; if, for instance, ' Festus, p. 171, s.u. nuncupata pecunia. Digitized by Microsoft® CHANGES IN NEXVM. 41 the debtor had agreed to pay at the end of one year, it might happen that a harsh creditor would enforce payment at the end of six months. This shows that the people were not feared as witnesses to the same extent as were the gods who presided over msiurandum and sponsio. The fact of the loan was proved beyond question by the witnesses present, but there was evidently no sacred virtue in the words which went with the loan, and these were not therefore binding simply because spoken in the people's hearing. This defect was what the XII Tables aimed at correcting. They thenceforth placed the verbal terms of nexum on as strong a footing as the words of sponsio. Conditions as to the amount of interest payable, the date of maturity of the loan, the security to be given by the debtor, could all now be inserted in the verbal nuncupatio. And still more important was the fact that the sum or amount of the loan itself could be verbally announced at the ceremony, so that if the debtor said " I hereby receive and am bound to repay fifty asses," this speech was as binding upon him as if the fifty asses had been actually weighed out to him in copper. As long as the money or corn was really weighed in the scales, nexum continued to be a natural and material method of loan ; but when by the introduction of coined money it became possible to count instead of weighing a given quantity of copper, then nexum tended to become an artificial and symbolical operation. The reason obviously is that counting is far more simple than weighing. Thus when a loan of 100 asses was being made. Digitized by Microsoft® 42 THE TWELVE TABLES. it became customary to name this sum in the nuncupatio without weighing it at all. The scales and witnesses appeared as before, but the scales were not used. The borrower, instead of taking 100 asses out of the scale-pan, simply struck it with a piece of copper so as to conform with the outward semblance of the transaction. Though the weighing had been dispensed with, yet by this rule of the XII Tables he was as much bound in the sum of 100 asses as though they had actually been weighed out to him. Hence the important efifect of the clause which I have quoted. Given a proper coinage that clause transformed the loan of money into a datio imaginana and the release of such a loan into an imaginana solutio. The outward form of neacum remained the same, but the actual process was greatly simplified. This change was doubtless not intended when the rule was made by the Decemvirs. It was the result of a more or less unconscious and probably gradual development. The genuine weighing and the fictitious weighing doubtless existed side by side. But it seems fairly certain that the introduction of coined money was another of the Decemviral reforms', and if so, we may assume that nexum changed from a ceremony perfoi-med with the scales into one performed with copper and scales (negotium per aes et libram) not long after the Decemviral legislation. II. Another important provision relating to nescum modified the harsh remedy hitherto appUed by the creditor against the delinquent debtor. 1 Mommsen, Som. Munzw. p. 175. Digitized by Microsoft® RESTRICTIONS ON POWER OF CREDITOR. 43 The words of the XII Tables have been fortu- nately preserved by Gellius', and run as follows: AERIS CONFESSI REBVSQVE IVRE IVDICATIS XXX DIES IVSTI SVNTO. POST DEINDE MANVS INIEGTIO ESTO. IN IVS DVCITO. NI IVDICATVM FACIT AVT QVIS ENDO EO IN IVRE VINDICIT SECVM DVCITO VINCITO AVT NERVO AVT COMPEDIBVS XV PONDO NE MINORE AVT SI VOLET MAIORE VINCITO. SI VOLET SVO VIVITO. NI SVO VIVIT QVI EVM VINCTVM HABEBIT LIBRAS FARRIS ENDO DIES DATO. SI VOLET PLVS DATO. There are two knotty points in the above passage. (1) What is the exact distinction between ac- knowledged money debts {aes confessum) and judg- ments obtained by regular process of Law (res iure iudicatae) ? (2) To what class of delinquents did the punishment apply ? (1) It can hardly be doubted^ that aes con- fessuTn included a debt contracted by nexum, as well as any other kind of debt the existence of which was not denied by the debtor. For example, a debt incurred by formless agreement or by sponsio would be an instance of aes confessum, provided the debtor admitted his liability. But in nexum this liability had already been admitted solemnly and before witnesses; to deny the existence of a nexal debt was impossible. Therefore aes confes- sum seems to be a term quite applicable to a debt contracted by nexum. The words aeris nexi were probably not used in the context because aeris confessi had a wider meaning, and this law 1 XX. 1. 43. ^ Ihering, G. d. R. B. i. 156, note. Digitized by Microsoft® 44 THE TWELVE TABLES. was apparently intended to cover much more than the one case of nexal indebtedness. The other class of debts here described as res iure iudicatae are no donbt judgment-debts. Where damages had been judicially awarded to one of the parties to an action, some means had to be provided of compelling payment from the other party. The executive in those early times was too weak to enforce its decisions, and self-help, as we have seen, was the usual resource of aggrieved persons. The only way in which the law could assist judgment creditors was by declaring what extent of retalia- tion they might lawfully take. And this brings us to the second question : (2) In what cases was the above mentioned manus iniectio to be exercised ? Voigt^ remarks that the XII Tables never mention manus iniectio as being a means of punishing default in a case of nexum. He then proceeds to state that the remedy for nexum was an actio pecuniae nuncupatae. Not only is this statement purely fanciful, as there is no mention of actio pecimiae nuncupatae in any of our authorities, but Voigt has surely ignored the evidence before him. Admitting, as we must, that nexum is included among the cases named at the beginning of the above clause, we can scarcely avoid the further conclusion long ago reached by Huschke that the rest of the clause, with its 30 days of grace, manus iniectio, ductio in ius, and all the consequences of disregarding the iudicatum, is a description of the punishment to which a breach of 1 XII Taf, I. 169. Digitized by Microsoft® JUDICIAL RECOGNITION OF NEXVM. 45 nexum might lead, as well as of that annexed to the other kinds of aes confessum and to res iure iudi- catae. The whole clause is one continuous state- ment, and to hold that the latter part of it, beginning at Ni IVDICATVM FACIT, provides a penalty solely for the case of judgment-debts, seems a very strained and unnatural interpretation. Why ex- plain iudicatum as referring only to judgment indebtedness ? Just before it in the text we find the direction IN ivs DVCITO, so that a nexal debtor after manus iniectio evidently had to be brought into court. The precaution was probably a new restraint upon the violence of creditors, in order that the justice of their claims and the propriety of manus iniectio might be judicially determined. But if a judge had to pronounce upon the validity of such proceedings, surely his decree might be de- scribed by the term iudicatum, as found in the above passage. It is no answer to say that the nature of aes confessum precludes the possibility of a judicial decision, and that therefore iudicatum can only refer to a res iure iudicata, that is, a judgment-debt. For in spite of this alleged dis- tinction we find here that debtors of aes confessum and judgment-debtors were treated in exactly the same way. Each of them was at first seized by his creditor and brought into court. Now why should this have been necessary in the case of a iudicatus more than in that of a nexus 1 For a judgment- debt seems to need judicial recognition just as little as a nexal debt. And yet we find that ductio in ius was prescribed in both cases. The only Digitized by Microsoft® 46 THE TWELVE TABLES. rational way of explaining the difficulty, seems to he to take iudicatum in the sense not of a judgment-debt but of a judicial decree, and to translate the passage as follows: "Let the creditor bring the debtor into court. Unless the debtor obeys the decree of the court or finds meanwhile a champion of his cause^ in the court, let the creditor lead him off into private custody, and fetter him" etc. etc. Thus the ductio in ius, the iudicatum, the domum ductio, and the directions as to the right kind of fetters and the proper quantity of food, must all have applied equally to aes con- fessum (including nexum) and to res iure iudicatae. This view is confirmed by the passage in which Livy '^ describes the abolition of the severe penalties of nexum,. The bill by which this was done or- dained, so Livy tells us, " nequis, nisi qui noxam meruisset, donee poenam lueret, in convpedibus aut in neruo teneretur . . .ita nexi soluti, cautumque in pos- teru/m ne necterentur." This law, the Lex Poetilia, was evidently passed for the relief of nexi, and relief was given by abolishing the use of compedes et neruum. Now as this was the very description of fetters given by the XII Tables in our text, it seems certain that the language of the Lex Poetilia referred to this clause of the Decemviral Code. Hence it follows that the punishment provided by this code was nexum, which is the view already deduced from the words of the XII Tables them- selves. The contrary interpretation, which is there- 1 PestuB, p. 376, s.u. uindex. ^ viii. 28. Digitized by Microsoft® FURTHER RESTRICTIONS. 47 fore probably erroneous, has strong supporters in Muirhead^ and Voigt^ But even though a iudicatum was thus necessary in order to permit the nexal creditor to lead off his debtor into custody, we may agree with Muirhead that the preliminary manus iniectio was within the power of the nexal creditor without any judicial proceed- ings. The nexum being a public transaction, a debt thereby contracted was so notorious as to justify summary procedure. Before the XII Tables, when self-help was subject to no regulations that we can discover, this summary procedure could be carried to all lengths in the way of severity and cruelty. But when the XII Tables had interposed the ductio in ius for the protection of nexal debtors, no other precaution against injustice was needful, and a preliminary trial before the manus iniectio would have been so superfluous that we cannot believe it to have ever been required. The elaborate provisions for the punishment of debtors did not end with the text which has come down to us and which has been quoted above. The substance, though not the actual wording, of the remainder of the law has fortunately been preserved by Gellius'. As far as our text goes, the proceedings consist of (1) manus iniectio, the arrest or seizure of the debtor by the creditor; (2) ductio in ius, the bringing of the debtor into court, that is, before the praetor or consid ; (3) iudi- catum, a decree of the praetor recognising the creditor's claim as just and the proceedings as ' B. L. p. 158. ^ XII Taf. i. 629. ' xx. 1. 45-52. Digitized by Microsoft® 48 THE TWELVE TABLES. properly taken. At this stage a uindex may step in on the debtor's behalf. What was the exact nature of his intervention we cannot know, but from Festus' definition he seems to have been a friend of the debtor, who denied the justice of his arrest and stood up in his defence. By the XII Tables he had to be of the same class as the debtor whom he defended^ and if his assertions proved to be false he was liable to a heavy fine^. If on the other hand his defence was satisfactory to the Court, further proceedings were doubtless stayed. But if no satis- faction was given either by the uindex or by the debtor, then (4) the creditor was entitled to lead home his debtor in bondage, though not in slavery, and to bind him with cords or with shackles of not less than 15 lbs. weight. Meanwhile the law as- sumed that the debtor would prefer to live upon his own resources. This shows that a nexal debtor was not always a bankrupt, and that it must often have been the will and not the power to pay which was wanting in his case. As there existed in those days no means of attaching a man's property, the only alternative was to attach his person. If however the debtor was really a ruined man and could not afford to support himself, the law bade the creditor to feed him on the barest diet by giving him a pound of corn a day, or more at the creditor's option. Here our textual information leaves off and we have to depend on Gellius' account. He says^ that this stage of domum duetto and uinctio lasted sixty days, and that during that period a com- ' Gell. XVI. 10. 5. 2 Festus, s. u. uindex. ' xx. 1. 46. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO NEXAL PENALTY. 49 promise might be arranged which would stay further proceedings. Meanwhile (5) on three successive nundinae, or market-days, the debtor had to be brought into the comitiuni before the praetor, and there the amount of his debt was publicly pro- claimed. This was a second precaution intended to protect the debtor by giving thorough publicity to the whole affair. At last (6) on the third market- day, and at the expiration of the sixty days, the full measure of punishment was meted out to the un- fortunate delinquent: he was addictus^ by the praetor to his creditor, and thus passed from temporary detention into permanent slavery. The extreme penalty is said by Gellius to have been either death or foreign slavery, and the words in which the former was enacted are given by him as follows: Tertiis nvndinis partis secanto. Si PLVS MINVSVE SECVERVNT SE FRAVDE ESTO. The meaning of these words has been much disputed, for ever since the beginning of the century many attempts have been made to soften their literal sense. We should a priori translate them thus : " On the third market-day let the creditors cut up and divide the debtor's body. If any should cut more or less than his proper share, let him not suffer on that account." That this is how the ancients understood the passage, we know from the testimony of Gellius, Quintilian^ and Tertullian^ But Gellius and Dio Cassius, though they had no doubts as to the meaning of the law, both say that 1 Gell. XX. 1. 51. ^ Inst. or. iii. 6. 64. ^ Apol. 4. B. E. 4 Digitized by Microsoft® 50 THE TWELVE TABLES. this barbarous practice of cutting a debtor in pieces was never carried out, so far as they knew, even in ancient times'. The law was therefore practically a dead letter. Some commentators, whose views are ably summed up by Muirhead'', make the most of this admission, and hold that the interpretation of "partis secanto" should be entirely different. They regard the division of the debtor's body between the creditors as too shocking a practice to have ever existed at Rome, and they take Secare to refer (as in the later phrase bonorwm sectio) to a sale and division of the debtor's property. In the event of his property being insuflScient to cover the debt, the debtor would then, as Gellius informs us, be sold into slavery "beyond the Tiber." The objections to this theory have been well pointed out by Niebuhr^. Not only is it opposed to all the ancient authorities, who knew at least the traditional meaning of the XII Tables as handed down to them through many generations, but it also conflicts with a well recognised principle of early Law. That principle was that the goods of a debtor were not responsible for his debts. His person might be made to suffer, but his property could not be touched. As we have seen, it was by no means unusual for a nexal debtor to support himself while in bondage. This can only be ex- plained on the supposition that neither his property nor his earnings were attachable by the creditor. It is this exemption of property which accounts for ' > Gell. XX. 1. 52. Dio Cass, fragm. 17. 8. 2 R. Law, p. 208—9. ^ B. G. i. 630. Digitized by Microsoft® EXTREME PENALTY WAS DEATH. 51 the severity of the nexal penalties. Now a sale and partition of the debtor's goods would have been quite inconsistent with the whole system of personal execution so plainly set before us in the rest of the law, whereas the killing of the debtor was but a fitting climax to his cruel fate. The inhumanity of the proceeding is not likely to have been perceived by men who tolerated such barbarities as the lex talionis and the killing of a son by his paterfamilias. When our classical authorities express their astonishment at the cruelty of the law, we must remember that they lived in a gentler age, in which the powers even of the paterfamilias were much curtailed ; and when they confess that they never knew of an instance in which the law was literally executed, we may discount their testimony by recollecting that the nexal penalties of the XII Tables were abolished centuries before they wrote. Comparative jurisprudence furnishes another argument in favour of accepting the literal sense of the phrase "partis secanto." Kohler^ has collected from different quarters various instances of customs which closely correspond with this harsh treatment of the Roman debtor. Unless therefore we dis- regard analogy, probability, and the whole of the classical evidence, we must clearly take the words literally and understand that the creditor could choose between selling his debtor into slavery "beyond the Tiber," or putting him to death. In the latter case, if there were more than one ' Shakesp. v. dem Forum der Jurisp. 4—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 52 THE TWELVE TABLES. creditor, they might cut up the body and each carry off a piece. III. There is a third clause of the XII Tables in which neim/m. is mentioned, but it does not alter the form of the contract. As far as we can make out, it simply declares that certain persons mys- teriously described as forcti et sanates shall have an equal right to the advantages of neaymn\ IV. Lastly there is a clause of the XII Tables intended to secure truthful testimony, that most essential safeguard to Tieocum: Qui SE SIEEIT tes- TARIER LIBRIPENSVE PVERIT NI TESTIMONIVM FATI- ATVR IMPROBVS INTESTABILISQVE ESTO. That is, whoever had been testis or libripens at the perform- ance of a nexum or mancipiwm was bound to give his testimony as to the fact of the transaction or as to its terms under penalty of permanent disqualification. This passage goes to show what we also gather from other authorities ^ that the libripens was a mere witness and not as some have supposed a public official. The phrase "qui libripens fuerit" would imply that any citizen might fill the position ; and since we find that the libripens was treated like any other witness it seems clear that he could not have been a public personage. We are now able to understand the meaning of Varro's remark : " liber qui suas operas in seruitutem pro pecwnia quam debet dat dum solueret nexus uocatur." This merely means that a man who had contracted a neooum, if unable to repay the ^ See Pestus s. u. sanates, Bruns Font. p. 364. 2 Gai. II. 107 ; Ulp. Eeg. xx. 7. Digitized by Microsoft® RESULTS OF LEGISLATION. 53 loan and therefore subject to an addictio, was obliged to serve like a slave, and retained the epithet of nexus till the debt was paid. On the whole then the legislation of the XII Tables produced two results: (1) By increasing the importance of the verbal part of the ceremony it increased the flexibility of the contract, and eventually changed it from a real into a symbolical transaction. The culminating point of the change was reached when the money constituting the loan was not weighed out, but merely named in the nuncupatio, while the borrower struck the scale-pan with a piece of copper. (2) By fixing certain limits to the violence of the creditor it softened the hardships endured by the nexal debtor. Though the extreme penalty of death was finally permitted, yet this could not be inflicted till the debtor had had many opportunities and ample time to clear himself The formula of neooum having now acquired great importance, its wording was doubtless soon reduced to a definite shape running somewhat as follows : " Quod ego tibi M lihras hoc aere aeneaque libra dedi, eas tu 7nihi...post annum... cum semissario foenore. . .dare damnas esto." This is the formula adopted by Huschke^ and modified by Rudorff. The words "damnas esto" appear to be wrongly rejected by Voigt, who disregards the analogy of the solutio though that seems our safest guide. The formula of nsad solutio is given by Gaius^ as follows, though Karlowa's reading differs consider- 1 Nexum, p. 49, etc. ^ iii. 174. Digitized by Microsoft® 54 THE TWELVE TABLES. ably from that of Huschke: "Quod ego tihi tot mill'ihus condemmatus sum, me eo nomine a te soluo ' liberoque hoc aere aeneaque libra: hanc tibi libram primam postremximque expendo secunduTn legem pvh- licam." Art. 3. The XII Tables did not, as far as we know, contain any clauses affecting sponsio or dotis dictio. The existence of those forms at such an early period has to be inferred from other sources, and we have seen that there is reason to assert their great antiquity, which the silence of the XII Tables cannot disprove. lusiurandum is known to have been approved by the XII Tables', but to what extent we cannot tell. We may therefore at once proceed to examine one of the most impor- tant innovations of the decemviral Code, namely the contract which despite its ambiguous name is known as the lex mancipi. Art. 4. Lex mancipi. This form, as its name indicates, was a covenant annexed to the transaction known as mandpiMm (later as mMnd- patio). Let us see first what mancipium was. Ulpian^ says that it was the mode of transferring property in res mancipi. Gains describes its use shortly as a fictitious sale', "imaginaria uenditio," and states that it could only be performed between Roman citizens, and applied only to res mancipi*. He describes the ceremony thus : — The parties meet in the presence of five witnesses and of a person (called libripens), who holds a pair of scales. The 1 Cic. Off. III. 31 and see above, p. 39. ^ Beg. xix. 3. 8 I. 113. ■> I. 119-20. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF THE LEX MANCIPI. 55 object of the transfer Gaius supposes to be a slave. The alienor remains passive, but the alienee, grasping the slave, solemnly declares aloud that he owns him by right of purchase ; then he strikes the scales with a piece of copper, and hands the piece to the alienor as a symbol of the price paid. Such is our meagre evidence as to the nature of mandpium. On this slender foundation of fact a vast amount of controversial theory has been heaped up. One certainty alone can be deduced from the evidence, that Tnancipium was not origi- nally a general mode of conveyance, as Gaius and XJlpian found it in their day, but that it began by being a genuine sale for cash, in which the price paid by the alienee was weighed in the scales and handed over to the alienor. The nuncupatio, or declaration made by the alienee, was merely explana- tory of his right of ownership, while the grasping of the object by the alienee and the acceptance of the price by the alienor were no doubt originally the essential elements in the transfer. The words spoken by the alienee probably had at first no more binding effect than the words of the borrower in nexum. We may be sure that in such a state of the law disputes would often arise as to the terms of the sale. And it was probably to prevent such disputes that the XII Tables made their famous rule: CVM NExyM FAOIET MANCIPIVMQVE VTI LINGVA NVNGVPASSIT ITA IVS ESTO. The extraordinary emphasis (not nuncu- passit but lingua mmcupassit) which is here laid on the verbal part of the ceremony is very striking. Bechmann rightly argues that it would be wrong to Digitized by Microsoft® 56 THE TWELVE TABLES. take this rule as referring only to the leges mandpi, but it would seem that it was to the language as ' distinct from the acts used in the ceremony that the XII Tables meant to give force and validity. The legal results which followed from seizing the object of sale in the presence of witnesses, and from weighing out the price to the seller, had long since been thoroughly well recognised. What the XII Tables now introduced was the recog- nition of the oral statement which accompanied those outward acts. We can hardly accept the sense which Bechmann has given to these words^. He notes the contrast between words and acts which is implied in the phrase lingua nuncupassit, but he thinks that the object of the rule was to reconcile the language of the transaction with its real nature. His view is based on the assumption that even before the XII Tables mancipium had changed from a genuine into a fictitious sale. In other words he assumes that while the alienee professed to buy the object with money weighed in the scales, he really weighed no money, but simply handed to the alienor a piece of copper, "quasi pretii loco." In fact the imaginaria uenditio of classical times was, according to Bechmann^, already in vogue. The purpose of the XII Tables was therefore to confirm this change, by declaring that the words and not the acts of the parties should henceforth have legal effect. It was as if this law said : " Pay no attention to the acts of the alienee, but listen to his oral statement. He merely delivers a piece of copper, 1 Kauf, I. p. 197. ■■' lb. p. 167. Digitized by Microsoft® CHANGES IN MANCIPIUM. 57 but do not imagine that this is the whole price due. In his declaration, the alienee states that the price is such and such. Let that be considered the real price of the object, and let the outward ceremony be regarded as a mere fiction." All this appears to be a very far-fetched interpretation of lingua nuTwupassit, and the assumption on which Bechmann has based it seems unwarranted, for two reasons : (1) We do not know that mancipium had already turned into an imaginaria uenditio. There is not one shred of evidence to prove that such a change had occurred before the XII Tables. So far indeed from preceding the XII Tables, the change would seem to have been directly caused by them. Until coin was introduced the weighing of the purchase-money was clearly necessary. If, as there is good reason to believe, coinage was first instituted by the Decemvirs^, the actual weighing must have continued till their time. If on the other hand we suppose that coined money was a much older institution (Cornelius Nepos de uir. ill. 7. 8. attri- butes its invention to Seruius Tullius), so that the actual weighing had long been dispensed with, man- cipium could still not have been an imaginaria uenditio, because (2) We can imagine no way in which a sale on credit could have been practised before the XII Tables. How could a vendor have permitted his property to be conveyed to a purchaser for a nominal and fictitious price, when the nuncupatio was as yet devoid of legal force ? After the uti lingua nuncu- ' See above, p. 42. Digitized by Microsoft® 58 THE TWELVE TABLES. passit of the XII Tables the nuncupatio doubtless specified the exact amount of the purchase-money, and this the alienor might lawfully claim. Moreover before the Decemviral reforms mancipium would have transferred full ownership to the purchaser, and the seller might have clamoured in vain for his money, unless he had previously taken security by means of vxidvmoniwm or sponsio. For since a well known provision of the XII Tables' was that no property should pass in things sold till the purchase- money was either paid or secured, we are bound to infer that before this the very reverse was the case/ and that property did pass even when the price had not been paid. Such having been the early law, how can we hold, as Bechmann does^, that the cash payment of the purchase-money was frequently not required, though the forms of weighing etc. were carried out in the original manner ? He urges' that credit, not cash, must often have been employed, because we caimot reasonably suppose that cash payment was possible in every case. But the force of this argument is weakened by the fact that mancipation was only practised to a limited extent. Tradition was the most ordinary mode of transfer employed in every-day life. And in a solemn affair such as mancipium, where five witnesses and a scale-holder had to be summoned before anything could be done, it cannot have been a great hardship for the purchaser to be obliged to bring his purchase- money and weigh it on the spot. Instead of credit purchases having been usual before the XII Tables, 1 2 Inst. 1. 41. , 2 j[^uf, I. p. 160. s ib. p. 1S8. Digitized by Microsoft® STATUTOPY OEIGIN OP LEX MANCIPI. 59 it seems likely that the XII Tables virtually intro- duced them. For by enacting that no property should pass until the price was paid or secured to the vendor, the Decemvirs made it possible for the conveyance and the payment of the price to be separately performed. Mancipium was thus made to resemble in one respect a modern deed. The vendor who has executed a deed, before receiving the purchase-money, has a vendor's lien upon the property for the amount of the price still owing to him ; and similarly the mancipio dans who had not received the full price, retained his ownership of the property until that full price was paid to him, or security given for its payment. We may therefore reject Bechmann's idea that the words lingua nuncupassit referred principally to the fixing of price in the nuncupatio. They simply gave legal force to the solemn oral state- ment made in the course of mancipium. On the one hand they bound the seller to abide by the price named, and to deliver the object of sale in the condition specified by the buyer. On the other hand they compelled the buyer to pay the full price stated in the nuncupatio, and to carry out all such terms of the sale as were therein expressed. In short, every lex mancipi embodied in the 7iun- cupatio became henceforth a binding contract. It is natural to inquire next what kind of agreement might constitute a lex mancipi. The nwncupatio placed by Gaius^ in the mouth of the purchaser runs thus: " Hunc ego hominem ex iure I 1. 119. Digitized by Microsoft® 60 THE TWELVE TABLES. Quiritium meum esse aio, isque mihi emtus esto hoc aere aeneaqiie libra." To this might no doubt be annexed various qualifications, and these were the leges in question. Voigt' indeed considers that these leges might contain every conceivable pro- vision, but Bechmann seems to come nearer to the truth in stating that no provision conflicting with the original conception of mancipiwm as a sale for cash could be inserted in the nuncupatio. For instance, Papinian states that no suspensive con- dition could be introduced into the formula of mancipiwm^. The reason of this obviously was that suspensive conditions are inconsistent with the notion of a cash sale. The purchaser could not take the object as his own and then qualify this proceeding by a condition rendering the ownership doubtful, A resolutive condition was also out of the question, for when the mancipium had transferred the ownership and the price was paid, it would have been absurd to say that the occurrence of some future event would rescind the sale. The transfer was in theory instantaneous, so that future events could not affect it. The following then are a few cases in which the lex mancipi could or could not be properly used: (a) The creation of an usufruct by reservation could be thus made', and the formula is given to us by Paulus : " Emtus mihi esto pretio dedvxito usu- frtijctu*." (b) Property could thereby be warranted free 1 XII Taf. II. 469. ^ y^t. Frag. 329. 3 Vat. Frag. 47. * Vat. Frag. 50. Digitized by Microsoft® USES OF LEX MANCIPI. 61 from all servitudes by the addition to the nuncupatio of the words "uti optimus matvimiisque sit^." The means by which the vendor was punished if the property failed to reach this standard of excellence will be presently examined. (c) The contents and description of landed property might be inserted in the nuncupatio, and if they were so inserted the vendor was bound to furnish as much as was agreed upon. Failing this, the deceived purchaser, so Paulus tells us^ could bring against the vendor an actio de modo agri, which entailed damages in duplum. (d) The accessories of the thing sold, destined to be passed by the same conveyance, would also doubtless be mentioned. (e) We might naturally have supposed that the quality of slaves or of cattle could have been described just as well as the content of an estate. Cicero says : " cum ex XII Tabulis satis erat ea praestari quue essent lingua nuncupata^," as though descriptions of all kinds might be given in the nuncupatio. Nevertheless Bechmann* has shown that such was not the case, inasmuch as we find no traces of any action grounded upon a false description of quality. The only actions which we find to protect mancipium are the actio auctoritatis and the actio de modo agri. There is no authority for supposing, as Voigt does^ that the actio de modo agri was not a technical but a loose term used by Paulus. According to Voigt, there was an action 1 18 Dig. 1. 59. ^ Sent. i. 19. 1. ^ Off. iii. 16. 65. « Eauf, I. p. 249. ^ XII Taf. 120. Digitized by Microsoft® 62 THE TWELVE TABLES. (the name of which has perished) to enforce all the terms of a nuncupatio of whatever kind. The so- called actio de modo agri would then have been only a variety of this general action. This theory is inadmissible: for in making his solemn list of the actiones in dztpZwm ^Paulus would hardly have used the clumsy phrase actio de modo agri, if there had been a comprehensive term including that very thing. Consequently, the description of slaves or cattle in the nuncwpatio does not seem to have been in practice allowed. The greater protection thus afforded to a purchaser of land than to one of other res mancipi may probably be explained by the fact that land was not and could not be con- veyed inter praesentes, whereas oxen or slaves could be brought to the scene of the mancipiwrn and their purchaser could see exactly what he was buying. (/) Provisions as to credit and payment by instalment might also be embodied as leges in the nwncupatio. This has been denied by Bechmann", Keller', and Ihering', but their reasons seem far from convincing. We may indeed fully admit their view for the period prior to the XII Tables, since there was then no coinage, and mancipium was an absolute conveyance of ownership. But when coinage had been introduced, when mancipium was capable of transferring dominium only after payment of the price, and when the oral part of mancipium had received legal validity from the XII Tables, the whole situation was changed. 1 Sent. I. 19. 1. 2 j^auf, i. p. 42. 3 Imt. 33. •> Geist d. R. R., ii. 530. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF CREDIT IN MANCIPIUM. 63 If it be said that credit is inconsistent with the notion of mancipium as an unconditional cash transac- tion, we may reply that this exceptional lex was clearly authorised by the XII Tables, since its use is implied in the legislative change above mentioned'. If it be urged that no action can be found to enforce any such lex, the obvious answer is that no action was needed, inasmuch as the ownership did not vest in the vendee till the vendor's claims were satisfied, and therefore if the vendee never paid at all the vendor's simple remedy was to recover his property by a rei uindicatio. Nor is there much force in the argument that clauses providing for credit would have been out of place in the nuncupatio because inconsistent with the formula " Hanc rem meam esse aio, mihique emta esto." On the one hand it is probably a mistake to suppose that this fixed form was always used, for the expression uti lingua nuncupassit seems clearly to imply that the oral part of mancipium and nexum was to be framed so as best to express the intentions of the parties, and the same conclusion may be drawn from the comparison of the formulae of mancipatio given in Gains I On the other hand, admitting that " hanc rem meam esse aio, etc." was a necessary part of the nuncupatio, it must have been used in mancipations made on credit, which by the XII Tables could not convey immediate ownership, and the existence of which in classical times no one denies. We are forced then to conclude either that "hanc rem meam esse aio" was not the phrase used at a sale on credit, or else 1 2 Inst. 1. 41 and see p. 58. '■' i. 119 and ii. 104. Digitized by Microsoft® 64 THE TWELVE TABLES. that it became so far a stereotyped form of words that it could be used not only in its literal sense but also as applying to credit transactions which the Decemviral Code so clearly contemplated. It is indeed inconceivable that if the price was, as every one admits, specified in the mmcupatio, the terms of payment should not have been specified also. It is worth while to notice how the legal conception of mandpium was indirectly altered by the XII Tables. That very important clause which prevented the transfer of ownership in things sold, until a full equivalent was furnished by the vendee^, had the effect of separating the two elements of which mancipimn consisted. Delivery of the wares and receipt of the price had at first been simul- taneous ; they now could be effected singly. Thus mancipium became a mere conveyance, and after a while, as was natural, the notion of sale almost completely disappeared, so that mancipium came to be what it was in Gains' system, the universal mode of alienating res mancipi. The lex mancipi, as we have now considered it, was an integral part of the formula of viancipium which the vendee or alienee solemnly uttered. Gains and Ulpian give us no hint that the vendor or alienor played any part beyond receiving the price fi:om the other party. But was this really so ? Could the vendee have known how to word his formula if the vendor had remained altogether silent ? We have therefore to enquire next (1) what share the vendor took in framing the 1 2 Inst. 1. 41. Digitized by Microsoft® THE vendor's dicta. 65 leges mancipi, and (2) how the lex mancipi was enforced against him. 1. The part played by the vendor is denoted in many passages of the Digest^ by the word dicere. In others the word praedicere^ or commemo- rare^ expresses the same idea, and we find that the vendor sometimes made a written and sealed decla- ration^. The object of such dicta was to describe the property about to be sold^ and they necessarily preceded the mancipium, or actual conveyance. They were thus no part of the mancipatory ceremonial and were quite distinct from the nuncupatio uttered by the vendee, which explains their not being mentioned by Gaius in his account of mancipatio^. It is to such dicta that Cicero doubtless alludes', when he says that by the XII Tables the vendor was bound to furnish only "quae essent lingua nimcupata" but that in course of time " a iureconsultis etiam reticen- tiae poena est constituta." The reticentia here mentioned was evidently not that of the vendee, but was a concealment by the vendor of some defect in the object which he wished to sell, and hence this passage is useful as showing the contrast between nuncupatio and dictu/m. The former might repeat the statements contained in the latter, thus turning them into true leges mancipi, and this ex- plains the fact that lex mancipi (or in the Digest lex uenditionis^), is sometimes used in the secondary 1 e.g. 21 Big. 1. 33, and 18 Dig. 1. 59. 2 19 Dig. 1. 21. fr. 1. » 19 Dig. 1. 41. * 19 Dig. 1. 13. fr. 6. 5 19 Dig. 1. 6. fr. 4. « i. 119. =■ Off. III. 16. 8 19 Dig. 1. 17. fr. 6. B. E. 5, Digitized by Microsoft® 6,6 THE TWELVE TABLES. sense of the vendor's dictum, as well as with the primary meaning of the vendee's nwncupatio. The leges embodied in the nuncupatio were thus binding on the vendor, whereas his dictum was at first of no legal importance. But in course of time the dicta Came also to be regulated, and though their terms were not formal and were never required to be identical with those of the nwncupatio, yet it was essential that the vendor in making them should not conceal any serious defects in the property. The dictum itself produced no obligation ; that could only be created by incorporating the dictum, into the nun- cupatio. The only function of dictum seems to have been to exempt the vendor from responsibility and from all suspicion of fraud. This is well illustrated by a case to which Cicero' refers, where Gratidianus the vendor had failed to mention, " nominatim dicere in lege mancipi " (here used in the secondary sense), some defect in a house which he was selling, and Cicero remarks that in his opinion Gratidianus was bound to make up to the vendee any loss occasioned by his silence. Bechmann^ questions whether the action brought against Gratidianus was the ocii'o eniti or the actio auotoritatis. But from the way in which Cicero speaks, it seems almost certain that he had been trying to bring a new breach of bona fides under the operation of the actio emti, and had not been pleading in a case of actio auctoritatis, which would scarcely have been open to such freedom of inter- pretation. We cannot therefore agree with Bech- mann that dicta not embodied in the nv/ncupatio 1 Or. 1. 89. 178. 2 Kauf, i. p. 257. Digitized by Microsoft® NVNCVPATIO AND DIOTIO DISTINGUISHED. 67 could be treated as nuncupata and made the ground for an actio auctoritatis, though we know that in later times they could be enforced by the actio emti. The distinction between the formal nuncupata and the informal dicta was never lost sight of, so far as we can discover from any of our authorities, nor is dictum ever said to have been actionable until long after the actio emti was introduced. The matters contained in the dicta of the vendor were descrip- tions : (i) of fixtures or of property passing with an estate', (ii) of servitudes to which an estate was subject^, (iii) of servitudes enjoyed by the estate^. It is noticeable that these are all mere statements of fact and that they exactly agree with the definition given by Ulpian*, who expressly excludes from dictum the idea of a binding promise. Thus the distinction between nuncujpatio and dictio may be briefly sum- marized as follows : Nwmupatio belonged only to mancipium,, whereas dictio might appear in sales of res nee mancipi as well as in mancipatory sales ^. Nuncupatio was a solemn and binding formula; dictio was formless and, until the introduction of the actio emti, not binding. Nuncupatio, as we have seen, did not touch upon the quality of the thing sold, whereas dictio might give, and eventually was bound to give, full information on this point. We must notice in conclusion what Bechmann 1 19 Big. 1. 26. = 21 Big. 2. 69. fr. 5. 3 Cio. Or. I. 39. 179. * 21 Big. 1. 19. « 19 Big. 1. 6. 5—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 68 THE TWELVE TABLES. has pointed out\ that lex, besides meaning a condi- tion embodied in a sale or mancipation, signified also a general statement of the terms of a sale or hire. This sense occurs in Varro", Vitruvius', Cicero* &c., and should be borne in mind, in order to avoid confusion and to understand such passages correctly. 2. The methods by which the true leges nuneit- patae could be enforced were two : (a) Actio de modo agri. Of this we only know that it aimed at recovering double damages from the vendor who had inserted in the nuncupatio false state- ments as to the acreage of the land conveyed^ (6) Actio auctoritatis (so called by modern civil- ians'). This was an action to enforce auctoritas, an obligation created by the XII Tables', whereby the vendor who had executed a mancipatory conveyance was bound to support the vendee against all persons evicting him or claiming a paramount title. Auctor apparently means one who supplies the want of legal power in another, and thereby assists him to maintain his rights. It is so used in tutela, of the guardian who gives auctoritas to the legal acts of his ward. In the present case, auctor means one who makes good another man's claim of title by defending it; and this explains why the obligation of auctoritas varied in duration according to the nature of the thing sold. Thus if the thing was a moveable (e.g. an ox) the auctoritas of the vendor lasted only one year, since the usucapio of the vendee made it un- 1 Eauf, I. p. 265. 2 £. ^ vi. 74. » i. 1. 10. « Part. or. 31. 107. ^ Leuel, Z. d. Sav. Stift. E. A. in. 190. s Lenel, Ed. perp. p. 424. ' Cic. Gaec. 19. 54. Digitized by Microsoft® SOURCE OF AV0T0RITA8. 69 necessary after that time. But if the thing sold was land, usucapio could not, by the XII Tables, take place in less than two years, and the avctoritas was prolonged accordingly ^ The penalty for an un- successful assertion of auctoritas was a sum equal to twice the price paid^. This shows that at the date of the XII Tables, as we have seen, mancipium was still a genuine sale and involved the payment of the full cash price. The same conclusion may be drawn from Paulus' express statement that unless the purchase money had been received no auctoritas was incurred. This last rule was a logical sequence of the enactment that no property vested until payment was fully made, since it was impossible that the vendee should need the protection of an auctor before he had himself acquired title. The question has been much debated whether this liability of a vendor to defend his purchaser's title arose ipso iure out of the mancipation, or whether it was the product of a special agreement. The latter view is held by Karlowa^, and Ihering*, but the weight of evidence against it seems to be overwhelming^ (a) Paulus* expressly states that warranty of title was given in sales of res nee maiicipi by the stipulatio duplae, but existed ipso iure in sales by mancipation. (6) Varro' says that if a slave is not conveyed 1 Cio. Top. i. 23. 2 Paul. Sent. ii. 17. 2-3. 3 L. A. 75. * Geist des R. R. m. 540. 5 See Girard, in N. E. H. de D. 1882. (6me Annge) p. 180. 6 Sent. II. 17. 1-3. ^ R. R. ii. 10. 5. Digitized by Microsoft® 70 THE TWELVE TABLES. by mancipation, his purchaser's title should be protected by means of a. stipulatio smvplae uel duplae, thus implying that in cases of mancipation such a step was unnecessary. (c) In recommending forms for contracts of sale, Varro advises the use of the stipulatio in sales of res nee mancipi'^, but gives no such advice and mentions no stipulatory warranty in the case of res mancipi. (d) We find that there were two ways in which the vendor could escape the liability of aitctoritas; either (i) he could refuse to mancipate^, or (ii) he could have a merely nominal price inserted in the nuncupatio (the real price being a matter of private understanding between him and the vendee), so that the penalty for failing to appear as auctor would be a negligible quantity. This we actually find in a man- cipatio HS nummo uno, of which an inscription has preserved the terms' where the object in mentioning so small a sum must have been to minimise the poena dupli in case the purchaser M'as evicted. Both these expedients to avoid liability are absolutely fatal to the theory of a special nwncupdtio as the source of auctoritas. In short from all this evidence we must conclude that after the enactment of the XII Tables mandpium contained an implied warranty of the vendee's title. The origin of the heavy penalty for failing to uphold successfully a purchaser's title has also been much debated. Bechmann'' attributes its severity to 1 R. E. n. 2. 6, and 3. 8. " Plant. Pers. 4. 3. S7. » Bruns, Font: 251. * Kauf, i. p. 121. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF PENALTY IN AYCTOBITAS. 71 a desire to punish the vendor who had suffered his vendee to say "hanc rem meam esse aio," when he knew that such was not the case. But this would have been to punish the vendor for reticentia, which was not done till much later times, as we know from Cicero; and moreover as we cannot be sure that the phrase " hanc rem meam esse aio " was invariably used in mancipium^, this view of Bechmann's comes too near to the theory of the nuncupative origin of auctoritas, not to mention the fact that it fails to explain why the penalty was duphmi instead of sim- plum. The best theory is probably that of Ihering-, who sees in the poena dupli a form of the penalty for furtum nee manifestum. It may be true, as Girard has pointed out', that the actio auctoritatis was not an actio furti in every respect. The sale of land to which the seller has no good title lacks the great characteristic of furtum, that of being com- mitted inuito domino, since the real owner of the land may often be entirely ignorant of the transaction. Still it is plaia that the conscious keeping and selling of what one knows to be another man's property is a kind of theft ; and, in that primitive condition of the law, it may have been thought unnecessary to impose different penalties on the hona fide vendor whose trespass was unconscious, and on the vendor who was intentionally fraudulent. This poena dupli can hardly be explained as a poena infttiationis, for if such, would not Paulus have been sure to mention it among his other instances of the latter penalty* ? i See above, p. 63. ^ Geist des R. R. in. 229. ' loc. eit. p. 216. " Paul. Sent. i. 19. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 72 THE TAVELVE TABLES. Auctoritas had to be supplied by the vendor whenever any third person, within the statutory period of one or two years, attacked the ownership of the vendee by a m uindicatio, or by a uindioatio libertatis causa if the thing sold was a slave, or by any other assertion of paramount title. Bechmann seems to be right in holding that the warranty of title also extended to all real servitudes enjoyed by the property, and to any other accessiones which had been incorporated in the nwncwpatio. To attack the vendee's claim in that respect was to attack a part of the res mancipata. Hence actio avctori- tatis was the remedy mentioned above' in connection with the true leges mancipi, and we may hold with Bechmann and Girard" that the actio auctoritatis and the actio de modo agri were the only available methods of punishment for the non-fulfilment of a lex mancipi. How the vendor was brought into court as aioctor is a question not easy to answer. But in Cicero ° we find an action described as being in auctorem praesentem, and apparently opening with the formula : " Quando in iure te conspicio, quaero anne fias auctor." The opening words do not lead us to suppose that the vendor had been summoned, but rather that he had casually come into court. This formula was probably uttered by the judge*, in every case of eviction, before the inauguration of the actio avxytoritatis, in order to give the defendant an oppor- tunity of answering and so of avoiding the charge. ' See above p. 61. ^ loc. cit. p. 203. 3 Gaec. 19. 64 ; Mm: 12. 26. < Lenel, Ed. Perp. p, 427. Digitized by Microsoft® FUNCTION OF THE AVOTOR. 73 If no answer was made to this question, the vendor was held to have defaulted, and the vendee might properly proceed to bring his actio auctori- tatis for punitive damages. But supposing that the ■aiictor duly appeared to defend his vendee, what were his duties ? It is not probable that he took the place of the vendee as defendant, because the word auctor does not seem to imply this, and because the vendor having conveyed away all his rights had no longer any interest in the property. The most probable solution seems to be that which regards the auctor simply as an indispensable witness. In the XII Tables we know^ what severe penalties were laid upon a witness who did not appear, as well as upon one who bore false testimony. Now an atictor who appeared but failed to prove his case was clearly a false witness, while one who failed to appear was an absconding witness. This was pro- bably an additional reason for the severe punishment inflicted on the auctor by the XII Tables. Thus "the ingenious supposition of Voigt'', that the vendor cannot possibly have incurred so heavy a penalty by mere silent acquiescence in the nuncupatio of the vendee, and must therefore have made a nuncupatio of his own in which he repeated the words used by the vendee, seems to be purely gratuitous as well as wholly unsupported by evidence. The last question to be considered is this: did •auctoritas apply solely to the warranty of things alienated by mancipium, or did it also apply to things alienated by in iure cessio ? An answer in 1 See above p. 52. » XII Taf. ii. 120. Digitized by Microsoft® 74 THE TWELVE TABLES. the broader sense is given by Huschke^ who cites Gaius^ as proving that mancipatio and in iure cessio had identical effects. But this is at best a loose statement of Gaius', and cannot prevail against the stronger evidence which goes to prove that auctoritas was a feature peculiar to mancipmm^ Bekker' points out that in iure cessio cannot have produced the obligation of auctoritas, because the in iure cedcTis took no part in the proceedings beyond making default, and could not therefore have made deceptive representations rendering him in any way responsible. In iure cessio must then have been from its very nature a conveyance without war- ranty, and Paulus confirms this inference by stating* that the three requisites of auctoritas were (i) man- cipatio, (ii) payment of the price, (iii) delivery of the res. We may then sum up the foregoing remarks by defining lex mancipi and auctoritas as follows : Lex mancipi in its primary meaning, was a clause forming part of the mmcupatio spoken by the vendee in the course of mancipiimi, and constituting a binding contract. It might embody descriptions of quantity, specifications of servitudes whether active or passive, conditions as to payment, and any other provisions not conflicting with the original conception of mancipium as a cash sale. In its secondary meaning, which we must care- fully distinguish, it referred to the dicta made by the vendor. ' Nexum, p. 9. ^ li. 22. s Akt. I. p. 33, note 10. * Sent. ii. 17. 1-3. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO FIDVOIA. 75 Thirdly, we even find it applied to the terms of sale as a whole, including nuncupatio, dicta, and any other private agreement between the parties respecting the sale. The two means of enforcing leos mancipi in the first sense were actio de modo agri and actio auc- toritatis. Auctoritas was an implied warranty of title intro- duced by the XII Tables into every mancipatory con- veyance, subject to the condition precedent that the vendee must have received the goods and paid the price. If the vendee was evicted, his proper remedy was the actio auctoritatis (most probably an instance of legis actio Sacramento'^), the object of which was to recover punitive damages of double the amount of the price paid, and which could be brought against the vendor within two years, if the object sold was an immoveable, and within one year, if a moveable. Since the lew mancipi is often credited with a still wider function, we are next brought to consider the agreement known as fidticia. Art. 5. FIDVCIA. This agreement is thought by many scholars to have been a species of lex mancipi, and consequently a creation of the XII Tables. Among those who thus regard fiducia as an agree- ment contained in the nuncupatio are Huschke^, Voigt', Eudorfif* and Moyle'. The first writer of any weight who disputed the correctness of this view 1 Girard, I.e. p. 207. ^ Nexum, pp. 76, 117. s XII Taf. II. 477. * Z. fur EG. xi. 52. 5 App. 2 to his ed. of the Inst. Digitized by Microsoft® 76 THE ITVEtVE TABLES. was Ihering^, and he has now been followed by Bek- ker", Bechmami', and Degenkolb*. The view held by these writers would seem to be the only tenable one. They assert that fiducia never was a part of manci- pium, but was simply an ancillary agreement tacked on to mancipium and couched in no specific form. The arguments againsb the former theory are : (1) That fiducia might exist in cases of in iure cessio as well as in cases of mancipium. Now in iure cessio gave no opportunity for the introduction of nuncupative contract. How then could a nuncu- patio containing a fiducia have been introduced among the formalities of the uindicatio ? (2) We know that the actio fiduciae was bonae fidei, and ionae fidei actions were of comparatively late introduction ; how then is this fact to be reconciled with the theory which derives fiducia from the nuncupatio of the XII Tables ? Voigt" states that the actio fidiuiiae was but one form of the ordinary action on a lex mxmcipi (it must be remembered that he regards every lex mancipi as having been actionable), but he gives no explanation of the surprising fact that fiducia alone of all the species of lex mancipi should have been provided with an actio bonae fidei. (3) If we admit, as we have done', that the only actions based upon mancipium are the actio auxitoritatis and the actio de modo agri, how can the actio fiduciae be classed with either ? 1 Geist des R. R. ii. p. S56. = Akt. i. 124. 3 Kauf, i. p. 287. « Z. fur RG. ix. p. 171. " XII Taf. II. p. 475. « supra, p. 68. Digitized by Microsoft® THE FWVOIAE INSTBVMBNTVM. 77 (4) The strongest piece of evidence which we possess in favour of Ihering's theory has appeared since he wrote. It consists of a bronze tablet in- scribed with the terms of a pactum fiduciae^ which Degenkolb" has carefully criticised and which seems to be conclusive in favour of our view. It contains, not a copy of the words used in mancipation, but a report of the substance of a fiduciary transaction. The mancipation is said to have taken place first, fidi fiduciae causa, and then the terms of the fiducia are said to have been arranged in a pactum conuen- tum between the parties, Titius and Baianus. It is evident from the language of the tablet that this fiduciary compact was independent of the mancipatio and informally expressed, so that any attempt, such as those made by Huschke and Rudorff, to reconstruct the formula of fiducia, and to fit such a formula into the nuncupatio of mancipium, is necessarily futile. Voigt' has even taken pains to give us the language used in the arbitrimn by which, according to him, fiducia was enforced. This bold restoration is a good instance of Voigt's method of supplementing history, but it cannot be said materially to advance our knowledge. We are nowhere told that fiducia could not be applied to cases of traditio, and a priori there is no reason why this should not have been the case. Yet all our instances of its use connect it solely with mancipatio or in iure cessio*, and all the 1 Printed in C. I. L. No. 5042 and Bruns, Font. p. 251. 2 Z. filr EG. IX. pp. 117—179. '' XII Taf. ii. p. 480. * Isid. Orig. v. 25. 23 ; Gai. ii. 59 ; Boeth. ad Gic. Top. iv. 10, 41. Digitized by Microsoft® 78 THE TWELVE TABLES. modem authorities, except Muther', are agreed in thus limiting its scope. If indeed we could extend fiducia to cases of traditio, it would be very hard to see why there should not have been a contractibs fiduciae as well as a contraxitus cotnmodati, depositi or pignoris. We know from Gains' that fiducia was often practised with exactly the same purpose as pignut or depositum, and we may reasonably infer that it was the presence of mancipaiio or in iure cessio which caused the transaction to be described, not as pigrms or depositum, but as fiducia. If we admit that fiducia was never connected with traditio, we can readily see why it never became a distinct contract. Bechmann' points out that in iure cessio or mancipatio was naturally regarded as the prin- cipal feature in such transactions as adoptions, emancipations, coemtiones, etc. The solemn transfer of ownership was in all these cases so prominent, that fiducia was always regarded as a mere pactum adiectum. If then we cannot admit fiducia to any higher rank than that of a formless pactum, it follows that the actio fiduciae, being borme fidei, and therefore most unlikely to have existed at the period of the XII Tables, must have originated many years later than fidvMa itself, which as a modification of mancipatio probably dated from remote antiquity; This may serve as an excuse for discussing ^tfcia in this place, although the XII Tables do not actually mention it. But it must have existed soon after that legislation, since it was the only mode of accom- 1 Sequestration, p. 337. " ii. 60. s Kauf, i. p. 293. Digitized by Microsoft® ARGUMENT FROM VSVBECEPTIO. 79 plishing the emancipation of a filiusfamilias as based upon the XII Tables. The theory that fiducia originated long before the actio fiduciae is corroborated by the account which Gaius gives' of the peculiar form of usucapio called usureceptio. This was the method by which the former owner of property which had been man- cipated or ceded by him subject to a fiducia could recover his ownership by one year's uninterrupted possession. It diflfered from ordinary usucapio only in the fact that the trespass was deliberate, and that immoveable as well as moveable things could be thus reacquired in one year instead of in two. This peculiarity as to the time involved may perhaps be explained by supposing that the objects of fiducia were originally persons and therefore res mobiles, or else consisted of whole estates which, like hereditates, would rank in the interpretation of the XII Tables as ceterae res. Now ii fiducia had been incorporated, as some think, in the formula oi mancipium, and had been actionable by means of an actio fiduciae based on the lex mancipi, could not the owner have recovered the value of his property by bringing this action, instead of having been forced to abide the tedious and doubtful result of a whole year's possession ? The fact noted by Gaius that where no money was paid no usureceptio was necessary, simply follows from the well-known rule that an in iure cedens as well as a mancipio dans did not lose his dominium until the price had been fully paid to him. We may therefore conclude that man- cipatio fiduciae causa resembled in its effect any 1 II. 59-60. Digitized by Microsoft® 80 THE TWELVE TABLES. other mancipatio. If this be the case, then fduda, as we have already said, must for many years have been an informal and non-actionable pactum, sup- ported by fides and by nothing else. Bechmann holds that' the object of the fiduciary mancipation was expressed in the nuncupatio by the insertion of the words fidi fiduciae causa, but this is a minor point which it is impossible to determine with certainty. Fiducia then may be briefly described as a formless pactum, adiectwm, annexed to Tmrndpatio or in iure cessio, but not originally enforceable by action, and therefore having no claim at this early date to be considered as a contract. Art. 6. VADIMONIVM is a contract which we know to have been mentioned and perhaps intro- duced by the XII Tables^. Gellius, however, speaks of the ancient uades' as having completely passed away in his time, so that in the opinion of Karlowa* we can scarcely hope to discover the original form of the institution. The most thorough inquiry into the question is that made by Voigt', who has treated the authorities and sources with the minutest care, but whose conclusions do not always seem to be well founded. Let us first examine the essence of the trans- action, a point as to which there is no doubt. Vas meant a surety, and uadimonium the contract by which the surety bound himself. Thus uadem 1 Kauf, I. p. 294. " Gell. xvi. 10. 8. » ibid. * L.A. p. 324. ^ Phil. Hist. Abhandl. der k. S. Ges. d. Wiss. viii. 299. Digitized by Microsoft® NATURE OF VADIMOS'irM. 81 poscere^ meant to require a surety, vadem dare to provide a surety, uadem accipere to take a man as surety for another man^, and uadari either to give surety or to be a surety*. From the point of view of the principal (uadimonium dans) uadimonium sistere meant to appear in due course ^ uadimonium deserere, to make default, while uadivionium differre meant to postpone the obligation which the ims had undertaken. The penalty for nonperformance was the payment (depen^io) by the uas of the sum pro- mised by his principal, who however was bound to repay him**. There might be more than one uas, and Voigt is probably right in stating that the svbuas was a surety for the performance of the obligation by the original uas''. There were two kinds of luidimonium, (i) that which secured the performance of some contract'; (ii) that which secured the appearance of the party in court, =bail'. Under the first of these heads Voigt places the satisdatio secundum mancipium which is found in the Baetic Fiduciae Instrumentumi as well as in Cicero", but whether or not this satis- datio was given in the form of a uadimonium must remain undetermined ; though, if it had been so given, we might perhaps have expected Cicero to use the technical phrase. 1 Cio. Rep. II. 36. 61; Var. L. L. vi. 8. 74. ' Cio. Fin. ii. 24. 79. ^ Cic. Brut. i. 18. 3. " Prise. Gram. i. 820. ^ Cic. Quint. 8. 29. 6 Cic. ad Brut. i. 18. 3. ; Plaut. Bud. 3. 4. 72. ' I. c. p. 307. ^ Varro, L. L. vi. 7. 71. » Cio. Off. IV. 10. 45. " ad Att. v. 1. 2. B. E. 6 Digitized by Microsoft® 82 " THE TWELVE TABLES. Next comes the question, in what form was uadimonium origiQally made ? The verbal nature of the primitive contract seems to be proved by the passages that Voigt quotes^ while he also completely denrolishes the old view which regarded uadimonium as having always been a kind of stipulation, and points out Varro's^ ex- press statement that uas and sponsor were not the same thing. On the other hand it is plain that uadimonium had come by Cicero's time to denote a mere variety of the stipulation, a fact which may be gathered from his language' and that of Varro*, as well as from the frequent use of promittere in passages describiag the contract. The later aspect of uadimonium, need not however detain us, and we may occupy ourselves solely with its primitive form. (a) Leist seems to think that both uadi- monium and praediatura were binding, like the spon^sio, in virtue of a sacred " word-pledge," or in other words that " Vas sum" " Praes swm'' had a formal value analogous to that of " Spondeo." This view he bases on the etymology of vms, praes and their cognates in the Aryan languages, but an ex- amination of Pott^ Curtius' and Dernburg' serves to show how entirely obscure that etymology is. If we cannot be sure whether uas is derived from fari, 1 Gic. ad Qu. fr. ii. 15. 3. ; Ovid, Am. i. 12. 23 : uadimmia garrula; etc. a L. L. VI. 7. 71. 3 Q„int. 7. 29. * loc. cit. 6 Etymol. Forsch. iv. p. 612. « Civ. Stud. iv. 188. ' Pfdr. I. 27.. Digitized by Microsoft® PRIMITIVE FOEM OF VADIMONIVM. 83 to speak, uadere, to go, or from an Indo-Germanic root meaning to bind, it is clearly impossible to build any theory on so iasecure a foundation. More- over, whatever the true etymology of uas may ultimately be proved to be, we can find in the above derivations no suggestion of a binding religious significance such as we discover in sponsio. (b) Voigt boldly assumes a knowledge of the ancient ceremony, and assigns- to the iwtdimonium connected with the sale of a farm the following formula : " Ilium fundum qua de re agitur tihi habere recte licere, haec sic recte fieri, et si ita faMum non erit, turn x aeris tihi dare promitto." This is not only purely imaginary, like many of Voigt 's recon- structed formulae, but the unilateral form in which it is expressed has no justification from historical sources. The scope of promittis? promitto in a stipulation is well established, but how can pro- mitto in an unilateral declaration have had any binding effect ? Voigt justifies his view by a com- parison with dotis dictio and iurata operarum pro- missio'^, but in both of these there was, as we have seen, a binding power behind the verbal declaration. The word promitto alone could never have produced the desired effect, unless we admit the principle laid down by Voigt^ that an unilateral promise was suffi- cient to create a binding obligation, which is merely to beg the question. If indeed we take promittere in its ordinary sense, we cannot doubt that uadimonium in Cicero's time was contracted by sponsio or stipu- 1 loc. cit. p. 315. ' lusNat. in. 178. 6—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 84 THE TWELVE TABLES. latio, but on the other hand it is equally certain that the ancient uadimonium, whatever it was, disappeared soon after the Lex Aebutia. The old form known to the Decemvirs cannot then be stated with the absolute certainty which Voigt seems to assume, but we may hazard one theory as to its nature which appears not im- probable, or at least far less so than that of an unilateral promissio. Gains' tells us that there were several ways of making uadimonia, and that one of them was the ancient method of iusiurandwm. That this was an exceptional method is proved by our rarely finding it in use^ and its adoption is almost inconceivable, except in the earliest times when the oath was fairly common as a mode of contract. We may be sure that the old uadimonium was embodied in some particular form of words, else it is hard to imagine how the penalty could have been specified. But if so, and if we exclude sponsio, as we are bound to do, what form of words could have had such binding force as an oath ? The rarity of this oath in Gellius' time may have induced him to state that it had quite disappeared', while Gaius may have mentioned it in order to make his list of vadimonia complete. Further, on examining the remedies for a breach of iitsiurandum*, we find that self-help was resorted to, just as it was in cases of neooum. And when self-help began to be restrained by law, the natural ' IV. 185. 2 e.g. 2 Dig. 8. 16. 3 See above p. 32. « See above p. 11. Digitized by Microsoft® POSSIBLE USE OF IV8IVRANDVU. 85 substitute would have been manus iniectio. Now there is good reason to believe that the early iwbdimonium was enforced by the legis actio per maniis iniectionem'^, and as Karlowa rightly says^, we cannot imagine such a severe penalty to have been entailed by an ordinary sponsio. lusiurandum, on the contrary, may easily have had this peculiarity, since it is the only form of verbal contract which we know to have been protected by means of self- help. Again, nanus iniectio seems to have been employed not only by the principal against the uas, but also by the uas against the principal. When Gaius states that sponsores were authorized by a Lex Puhlilia to proceed by manus iniectio against a principal on whose behalf they had spent money (depensum), he seems to show that facts and circumstances were sometimes recognized as a source of legal obligation. But we are bound to reject this ex- planation, since no obligation ex re was recognized until much later in the Roman jurisprudence. It is far more likely that, as Muirhead suggests^, the Lex Puhlilia merely extended to sponsores the remedy already available to nodes; so that sponsio became armed with the manus iniectio simply on the analogy of its older brother uadimonium. The theory here put forward as to the early form of uadim.oniu/ni must remain a pure conjecture in the absence of positive evidence; but its connection with iusiurandum is at least a possibility. 1 Karlowa, L. A. p. 325 : Voigt, XII Taf. ii. 495. 2 L. A. p. 324. 3 R. L. p. 166. Digitized by Microsoft® 86 THE TWELVE TABLES. This vexed question may then be summed up as follows : (i) In the legal system of the XII Tables uadimonium was a contract of suretyship, possibly entered into by iusiurandwm, and probably entailing manus iniectio, (a) if the surety (uas) failed to fulfil his obligation, or (b) if the principal (uadimonium dans) failed to refund to his surety any money expended on his behalf (ii) In later times uadimonium was clothed in the ordinary sponsio and its old form had completely disappeared. Art. 7. There are a few other fragmentary provisions in the XII Tables, which relate to contracts and require a brief notice. I. Paulus^ speaks of an actio in duplimi as given by the XII Tables ex causa depositi. This cannot have had any connection with the actio depositi of the Institutes and Digest, for the latter was an invention of the Praetor {honoraria), and therefore could not have appeared till towards the end of the Kepublic, while its usual penalty was simplum, not duplum. Voigt explains^ this action of the XII Tables as an instance of actio fduciae based upon a fiducia cvrni amico. But we cannot admit that fiducia at such an early period was actionable at all', and still less can we base on Voigt's assumption the further theory that every breach of fiducia must have had a penalty of du- plum annexed to it. The conjecture made by 1 Sent. II. 12. n. ^ XII. Taf. ii. 4. 79. ' See above, page 78. Digitized by Microsoft® ACTIO EX CAV8A DEPOSIT!. 87 Ubbelohde' that the actio ex causa depositi of the XII Tables was an actio de perfidia seems still more rash than that of Voigt, and has deservedly met with but little favour. There are two points to be noted in this state- ment of Paulus : (i) He states that the action was ex causa depositi: he does not call it actio depositi. (ii) He does not say how the depositum was made, but implies that it might be made by traditio as well as by Tnancipatio, which also goes against Voigt 's theory. It was an ancient rule^ that if a man used the property of another in a manner of which that other did not approve, he was guilty of common theft, and was punishable in duplum like any other fur nee manifestus. It seems therefore quite reasonable to suppose that the XII Tables mentioned this kind o{ furtumi as arising ex causa depositi. If so, the penalty of duplum mentioned by Paulus is no mystery. It was merely the ordinary penalty as- signed to furtum nee manifestum, and depositum as a contract had nothing to do with it. Hence this actio ex causa depositi does not properly belong to our subject at all. II. Gaius° says that by the pignoris capio of, the XII Tables (a) the vendor of an animal to be' used for sacrifice could recover its value if the purchaser refused to pay the price, and (6) a man who had let a beast of burden in order to raise money for a sacrifice could recover the amount of 1 Gesch. der ben. R. G. p. 22. ^ gai. iii. 196. » iv. 28. Digitized by Microsoft® 88 THE TWELVE TABLES. the hire. Hardly anything is known of the legis actio per pignoris capionem, but it was evidently some proceeding in the nature of a distress, through which the injured party could make good his claim by seizing the property of the delinquent. The only points in which this passage of Gains is in- structive are these. First, we are here shewn what were evidently exceptional instances of the legal liability of a man's property, as distinguished from his person, for his breaches of agreement. Secondly, we here have conclusive proof that the consensual contracts of sale and hire were unknown at the period of the XII Tables : these two special in- stances in which the contracts were first recognised were both of a religious nature, and the makers of the XII Tables do not seem to have dreamt that other kinds of sale or hire needed the least protec- tion. Thus for many years to come the most ordinary agreements of every-day life, such as hire, sale or pledge, were completely formless, depended solely on the honesty of the men who made them, and were not therefore, properly speaking, contracts at all. The principle of the old Roman law that neither consent nor conduct could create an obliga- tion ex contractu, but that every contract must be clothed in a solemn form, appears in the fullest force throughout the XII Tables. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER IV. THE DEVELOPMENT OF CONTRACT. At the threshold of a new period we may pause to review briefly the ground already covered, and to observe the very different aspect of our future field of inquiry. We find the legal system of the XII Tables to have possessed five distinct forms of contract, iusiurandum (including uadimonium ?), sponsio, dotis dictio, neooum, and leoc mancipi. But though the list sounds imposing enough, these forms were still primitive and subject to many serious limitations : (i) Roman citizens only were capable of using them, and hence they were useless for purposes of foreign trade. (ii) They all alike required the presence of the contracting parties, and were therefore available only to persons living in or near Rome. (iii) They all required the use of certain formal words or acts, so that, if the prescribed formula or action was not strictly performed, the intended contract was a nullity. (iv) The remedies for a breach of contract, except in the case of nexum and lex mancipi, were probably of the vaguest description, and may have consisted only of self-help carried out under certain pontifical regulations. Digitized by Microsoft® 90 THE DEVELOPMENT OF CONTRACT. A system with so many flaws was plainly incapable of meeting the many needs which grew out of immense conquests and rapidly extending trade. Accordingly by the end of the Republic we find that the law of contract had wholly freed itself from every one of these four defects : (i) Contracts had been introduced in which aliens as well as Romans could take part. (ii) Means had been devised for making con- tracts at a distance. (iii) Forms had by degrees been relaxed or abolished. (iv) Remedies had been introduced by which." not only the old contracts but all the many new. ones were made completely actionable. The question now before us is: how had this wonderful development been achieved ? It is customary in histories of Roman Law to subdivide the period from the XII Tables to the end of the Republic into two epochs, the one before the Lex Aebutia, the other subsequent to that law. The reason for this subdivision is that the Lea: Aebutia is supposed to have abolished the legis actio procedure and to have introduced the so-called formulary system, which enabled the Praetors to create new forms of contract by promulgating in their Edict new forms of action. Such a division doubtless has the merit of giving interest and definiteness to our history, but it has two great drawbacks : First, that we do not know what the Lex Aebutia did or did not abolish ; and secondly, that its date is impossible to determine. Digitized by Microsoft® OBSCURITY OF LEX AEBVTIA. 91 As to its provisions, the two passages in which the law is mentioned by Gains ^ and Gellius''' merely prove that the legis actio system of procedure and various other ancient forms had become obsolete as a result of the Lex Aebutia. But that these were not suddenly abolished is proved by the well-known fact that Plautus and Cicero refer more often to the procedure by legis actiones than they do to that per formulas. The most plausible theory seems to be that which regards the Lex Aebutia as having merely authorized the Praetors and Aediles to publish new formulae ia their annual Edicts. But even this is nothing more than a conjecture. The date of the Lex Aebutia (probably later than A. V. C. 500) is also involved in obscurity, as is proved by the fact that scarcely two writers agree upon the question". It seems clear that a law about which so little is known is no proper landmark. The plan here adopted will therefore be a different one. We shall content ourselves with a detailed examination of each of the kinds of contracts which we know to have existed at Rome between the XII Tables and the beginning of the Empire, treating in a separate section of each contract and its history down to the end of the period. By this means we may avoid confusion and repetition, though the period in hand, extending as it does over nearly five hundred years, is perhaps inconveniently large to be thus treated as a whole. 1 IV. 30. ' XVI. 10. 8. ' A. V. c, 584 according to Poste and Moyle ; 513 aecording to Voigt ; 507 according to Muirhead ; etc. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER V. FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. Art. 1. Nexvm. The severity and unpopu- larity of nexum did not prevent its continuance for at least one hundred years after the modifications made in it by the XII Tables. Its character remained unchanged, until at last the Roman people could suffer it no longer. In A. v. c. 428' a certain nesous was so badly treated by his credi- tor that a reform was loudly demanded. The Lex Poetilia Papiria was the outcome of this agitation. Cicero', Livy' and Varro* have each given a short account of the famous law, and from these it may be gathered that its chief provisions were as follows : (i) That fetters should ia future be used only upon criminals. (ii) That all insolvent debtors in actual bondage who could swear that they had done their best to meet the claims of their creditors °, should be set free. 1 According to Liyy, but Dionysius makes it 452. 2 Bep. II, 30. 40. 59. s viii. 28. * L. L. vii. 5. 101. ' Next qui bonam copiam iurarent : cf. Lex lul. Mun. 113, Digitized by Microsoft® LEX POETILIA PAPIRIA. 93 (iii) That no one should again be neccus for borrowed money, i.e. that manus iniectio and the other ipso iure consequences of nescum should henceforth cease. Varro is the one writer who mentions the qualification that it was only nexi qui honam copiam iurarent who were set free. But Cicero and Livy may well have thought this an unnecessary detail, considering what an immense improvement had been made by the statute in the condition of all future borrowers. A clause of the Lex Coloniae luliae Genetiuae^ shows that imprisonment for debt was still permitted, but that the effects of ductio were much softened, the uinctio neruo ant compedibus and the capital punishment being abolished along with the addictio. But diici inhere was still within the power of the magistrate^, and Karlowa" seems to be right in holding that this was not a new kind of ductio originating subsequently to the Lecc Poetilia. The Praetor doubtless always had the power to order that a iudicatus should be taken and kept in bonds. But this was a very different thing from the utterly abject fate of the nexus under the XII Tables. It was only therefore the special severities consequent upon nexum that can have been abolished by the Lex Poetilia. Nexum itself was not abro- gated, for the way in which later authors speak of it shows that there still survived, if only in theory, a form bearing that name and creating an obligation. But as soon as its summary remedies were taken 1 cap. 61; Bruna, Font. p. 119. 2 Lex Bubr. cap. 21 ; Bruns, Font. p. 98. ^ L. A. p. 165. Digitized by Microsoft® 94 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. away, neocum became less popular as a mode of contract and gave way to the more simple obligatio uerbis. Another reason for its being disused, wlien it no longer had the advantage of entailing capital punishment, was that the introduction and wide- spread use of coinage made the use of scales unnecessary. Stipulatio, which required no acces- sories and no witnesses, was now the easiest mode of contracting a money loan. We shall see in the next section that it came to have still further points of superiority, and thus it was certain to supersede newum, when neoswii ceased to have special terrors for the delinquent debtor. The solutio per aes et libram which we find in Gaius, as a survival of solutio nesd, was not the release of nexii/m, but the similar release used for discharging a legacy per darrmationem or a judgment debt. Its continued existence is no proof that neam/rn survived along with it, for in later days it had nothing to do with the release of borrowed money. But though nexum proper certainly died out before the Empire, we have seen' how the meaning of the word became more vague and com- prehensive. By the end of the Republic we find neocum used to describe essentially different trans- actions, and simply denoting any negotiwm per aes et libram. Art. 2. Sponsio and stipvlatio. The origin and early history of sponsio have already been considered. There is no authority for Bekker's opinion that sponsio was enforceable before the XII Tables by the legis 1 See above p. 24. Digitized by Microsoft® THREE USES OF SPOHiSIO. 95 actio Sacramento^, nor do we know that it gave rise to any action, but notwithstanding this fact we have seen good reason for concluding that it existed at Rome from the earliest times. As we found that its origin was religious, and as the XII Tables do not mention it, we may regard the remedies for a breach of sponsio as having been regulated by pontifical law, down to the time when condictiones were introduced. In the law of this last period sponsio appears in three capacities : (1) As a general form of contract adapted to every conceivable kind of transaction. (2) As a form much used in the law of pro- cedure. (3) As a mode of contracting suretyship. Its binding force was the same in all these three adaptations, but its history was in each case different. Thus sponsio was used as a general form of contract down to the time of Justinian, though it had then long since disappeared as a form of suretyship. And there were statutes affecting the sponsio of surety- ship which had nothing to do with the sponsio of contract or of procedure. It will therefore be con- venient to treat, under three distinct heads, of the three uses to which sponsio became adapted, remem- bering always that in form, though not in all its remedies, it was one and the same institution. I. Sponsio as a general form of contract. We have seen that the form of sponsio consisted of a question put by the promisee and answered by the promisor, each of whom had to use the 1 AU.i. p. 147. Digitized by Microsoft® 96 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. word spondere. For example : Qu. : " Sponden ticam gnatam filio uxorem meo ? " Ans. : " Spondeo^." Qu. : "Centum dari spondes?" Ans.: " Spondeo^." This form was available only to Roman citizens. But there subsequently came into existence a kindred form called stipulatio, which could be used by aliens also, and could be expressed in any terms whatsoever, provided the meaning was made clear and the question and answer corresponded. The connection between sponsio and stipulatio is the first question which confronts us. There is no doubt that sponsio was the older form of the two, because (i) it alone required the use of the formal word spondere, (ii) it was strictly iuris ciuilis, where- as stipulatio was iuris gentium^, and (iii) it had to be expressed in the present tense (e.g. dari spondes?) whereas stipulatio admitted of the future tense (e.g. dabis ? fades ?), which Ihering^ has shown to be a sign of later date. Since the rise of the tits gentivm, was certainly subsequent to the XII Tables, we are justified in ascribing to the stipulatio a comparatively late origin, though the precise date cannot be fixed with certainty. Though stipulatio was a younger and a simpli- fied form, yet it is always treated by the classical jurists as practically identical with sponsio. Both were verbal contracts ex interrogatione et responsione, and their rules were so similar that it would have been waste of time and useless repetition to discuss them separately. 1 Varro, L. L. vi. 7. 70. ^ Qaius in. 92. 3 Gaius loc. cit. * Geist d. B. B. ii. 634. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF 8TIPVLATI0. 97 The derivation of stipulatio has been variously given. Isidorus^ derived it from stipula, a straw ; Paulus Diaconus^ and Varro" from stips, a coin; and the jurist Paulus*, followed by the Institutes, from stipulus, firm. The latter derivation is doubt- less the correct one^ but it does not help us much. What we wish to know is the process by which a certain form of words came to be binding, so that it was distinctively termed stipulatio, the firm trans- action. Now if we conclude, as Voigt does', that the stipulatio and the sponsio were both imported from Latium, their marked difference with respect to name, age and form must remain a mystery. Whereas we may solve, or rather avoid, this diffi- culty by acknowledging that sponsio was the parent of stipulatio, and that the latter was but a further stage in the simplification of sponsio which had been steadily going on since the earliest times. We have already reviewed the three stages through which sponsio seems to have passed. Stipulatio in all probability represents a fourth and wider stage of development. The binding force of a promise by question and answer, apart from any religious form, at last came to be realized after centuries of use', and as soon as the promise became more conspicuous than the formal use of a sacred word, the word spondere was naturally dropped, and with 1 Orig. 5. 24. - s. u. Stipem. 3 L. L. VI. 7. 69-72. * Sent. v. 7. 1. ^ See Ihering, Geist ii. § 46, note 747, who compares the German Stab, Stift, bestatigen, bestiindig. 6 lus Nat. II. 238. '' Ihering, Geist ii. p. 585. B. E. 7 Digitized by Microsoft® 98 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. it fell away the once descriptive name sponsio, to make way for that of stipulatio, now a more correct term for the transaction. Thenceforward, as a matter of course, stipulatio became the generic name, while sponsio was used to denote only the special form spon- desne? spondeo. The precise date of the final change is a matter of guess-work. But as stipulatio was the form avail- able to aliens^ it was probably the influx of strangers which made the Romans perceive that their old word spondere, only available to Roman citizens, was inconvenient and superfluous. Unless contracts with aliens had become fairly common, the need of the untrammelled stipulatio would hardly have been felt. Therefore it seems no rash conjecture to suppose that the stipulatio was flrst used between Romans and aliens, and first introduced about A.V.C. 512*, the date generally assigned to the creation of the new Praetor qui inter peregrinos ius dicebat. As to the form of the stipulatio : (a) Ihering* and Christiansen* have expressed the opinion that originally the promisor did not merely say spondeo, faciam, daho, etc., as in most of the known instances, but repeated word for word all the terms of the promise as expressed in the question put by the promisee. This view is based upon the passages in Gaius^ and the Digest*, which lay great stress upon the minute correspondence necessary between the question and the answer in a vaHd ' Gai. III. 93. 2 Liu ^^j-^ ^ix. » Geist II. 582. * Inst, des B. B. p. 308. •^ in. 92. « 45 Dig. 1. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® VARIOUS STIPULATORY FORMULAE. 99 stipulation. It is hard to see how such a rule could have arisen unless there had been some danger of a mistake in the promisor's reply, and if this reply had been confined to the one word spondeo, promitto, or faciani, a mistake would hardly have been possible. Hence this view seems highly pro- bable. (b) Voigt"^ has given the following account of the origin of the various formulae. (i) The form spondesne ? spondeo is the oldest of all, and dates back into very early times ^ which is probably quite correct. But in a more recent work' this view expressed in "lus Naturale" is unfor- tunately abandoned, and Voigt regards sponsio as a Latin innovation dating from the fourth century of the City. This seems surely to place the birth of sponsio far too late in Roman history. (ii) The looser form dabisne ? dabo is found in Plautus*, and was no doubt, as Voigt says^ a product of the ius gentium and first introduced for the benefit of aliens. (iii) Lastly, the origin of the forms promittis ? promitto, and fades? faciam^, is placed by Voigt not earlier than the beguming of the Empire. But his reasons for so doing seem most inadequate. If the form dabisne? dabo occurs in Plautus, the form fades? fadam, which is essentially the same, can hardly be attributed to a later period. And since 1 Ius Nat. IV. 422 ft. 2 See Liu. iii. 24. 5, A.v.c. 295, and iii. 56. 4, A.v.c. 305. 3 Bom. RG. i. p. 43. ■• Pseud. 1. 1. 112, A.v.c. 663. 5 /. N. IV. 424. « Of. Gaius, in. 92. 116. 7—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 100 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. prondttam is used by Cicero as a synonym for spondea/m}, and fidepromittere was an expression used in stipulations, as Voigt admits, two centuries before the end of the Republic'-', it seems rash to affirm that promittere, the shortened phrase, was not used in stipulations until the time of the Empire. We may therefore attribute both of these forms to republican times. (c) The admissibility of condicio and dies as qualifications to a stipulation must always have been recognized, since a promise deals essentially with the future and requires to be defined. (d) The insertion of a conventional penalty into the terms of the contract was probably practised from the very first, whenever facere and not dare was the purport of the promise, because the candictio certi was older than the condictio incerti, and there- fore for many years an unliquidated claim would have been non-actionable unless this precaution had been taken. We have now seen that verbal contract by ques- tion and answer, whether called sponsio or stipulatio, existed long before it became actionable. When it finally became so is uncertain, though we know what forms the action took. (a) Condictio certae pecuniae. Gains' speaks of a Lex Silia as having introduced the legis actio per condictionem for the recovery of certa pecunia credita. This law is mentioned nowhere else, and its date can only be approximately fixed. 1 Cic. pro Mur. 41. 90. ^ I. N. iv. 424, note 77. -' IV. 19. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF PECTNIA CBEDITA. We know from Cicero^ that pecwnia credita, a re" money loan, might in his time originate in ways, by datio (mutuum), expensilatio, or stipulatio. But we cannot infer from this that the Lex Silia made all those three forms of loan actionable'', for mutuum and expensilatio, as will presently be seen, were certainly of more modern origin than the condictio certae pecuniae. It appears indeed that stipulatio was the original method of creating pecunia credita^: consequently the Lex Silia must have simply provided for the recovery of loans made by sponsio or stipulatio. It is noticeable, moreover, that Gaius speaks as though by this law money debts had merely been provided with a new action : he does not imply that stiptdatio or sponsio was thereby introduced, as Voigt'' and Muirhead' have ventured to infer. Their view is surely an un- warrantable inference, for if the Lex Silia had created so new and important a contract as stipu- latio, Gaius would hardly have expressed so much surprise at the creation of a new form of action to protect that contract. His language seems clearly to imply that pecunia credita was already known, and was merely furnished by this law with a new remedy. We may conclude then that pecunia credita must have existed before the Lex Silia, and can only have been created by stipulatio. Stipulatio ' Rose. Com. 5. 14. ^ Puohta, Imt. 162. 3 Cf. the dare, credere, expensum ferre of the Instrumentum fiduciae in Bruns, p. 2-51, with the dare, gtipulari, and expensum ferre of Rose. Com. 5. 13-14, and see Voigt, lus Nat. it. 402. * Ills Nat. II. 243. ■' R. L. p. 230. Digitized by Microsoft® 102 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. cannot, therefore, have been introduced by this law, though it probably was thereby transferred from the religious to the secular code. The age of the Lex Silia has been variously given', but there are no trustworthy data, and any attempt to fix it must be somewhat conjectural. The only thing we do know is that this law must have been enacted a considerable time before the Lex Aquilia of A.V.C. 467, for the latter law pun- ished" the adstipulator who had given a fraudulent release, and as this release must have applied to the stipulatio certae rei of the Lex Galpurnia', it is evident that the Lex Aquilia must have been younger than the Lex Calpurnia, which, as we shall see, was itself younger than the Lex Silia. We may perhaps approximate even more closely to the date of the Lex Silia. Muirhead^ has con- jectured with much plausibility that the introduction of the condictio certae pecmviae was a result of the abolition of the nexal penalties, or in other words that the Lex Silia followed soon after the Lex Poetilia of A.v.c. 428. There are several strong points in favour of this hypothesis : (i) It explains Gaius' difiiculty as to the reason why condictio was introduced. For when the terrors of nexum were abolished, it was natural to substitute some penalty of a milder description and not to let defaulting debtors go entirely unpunished. Now 1 A.V.C. 311 to 329, according to Voigt, I. N. iv. 401. " Gai. III. 215. ' Of. quanti ea res est in Gai. loc. cit. with 13 Dig. 3. 4. * R. L. p. 230. Digitized by Microsoft® PROBABLE OBJECT OF LEX SILIA. 103 this is just what the condictio certae pecuniae, with its sponsio poenalis tertiae partis, presumably accomplished, for like neocum it dealt only with pecunia. (ii) This hypothesis helps us also to understand why the condictio certae pecuniae should have been introduced before the cmidictio certae rei, thus making a stipulation of certa pecunia actionable, while a stipulation of res certa had not this protec- tion. As we found above', the introduction of coin must have made the stipulatio certae pecuniae a very convenient substitute for nexiom. It was therefore natural to give a remedy to this stipidatio and so to make it take the place of nexum as a binding contract of loan ; while certa res, never having had and therefore not immediately requiriag a remedy, was not protected by condictio until several years later. (iii) We can also see why the condictio ceiiae pecuniae should have been the only condictio fur- nished with so severe a penalty as the sponsio poenalis. It was because money loans had been jealously guarded in the days of nexum, and it was therefore thought proper to protect the money loan by stipulation far more carefully than the promise of a res certa. All these seem strong points in confirmation of Muirhead's hypothesis. By connecting stipulatio and condictio with the downfall of nexum and of its manus iniectio, we not only get a plausible date for the Lex Silia, but what is far more important, we 1 p. 94. Digitized by Microsoft® 104 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. obtain a satisfactory explanation of the curious fact that, while stipulationes were made actionable, they were not all made so at once. The forms of condictio under the legis actio system are not known, but under the formulary system, this condictio had the following formula: Si paret N^ N'egidium A" Agerio HS X dare oportere, iudesc, iV™ Negidium A" Agerio X condemna. s. n. p. a} Its peculiar sponsio will be given in another place. (b) Condictio triticaria or certae rei. The Lex Calpurnia, which must have preceded the Leoo Aquilia^ and must therefore have been enacted earlier than A.v.C. 467, extended the legis actio per condictionem to stipulations of triticum, corn, {condictio triticaria) ; and this, being soon interpreted by the jurists as including every debt of res certa, gave rise to the condictio certae rei. This new kind of condictio omitted, for the reason above '-stated, the sponsio and restipulatio tertiae partis, in place of which the defendant merely promised to the plaintiff a numnvus wnus which was never exacted or paid*. Therefore, as the severer law invariably precedes the milder, we might be sure that the Lex Silia with its heavy penalty was older than the Lex Calpurnia with its nominal fine*, even if Gains had not clearly led us to this conclusion by the order in which he mentions the two laws'. The formula ran thus : Si paret N'^ Negidiwm A" Agerio tritici optimi X modios dare oportere, qvtanti 1 Gai. IV. 41. Lenel, Ed. Perp. 187. ^ See above, p. 102. » p. 103. * Voigt, I. N. III. 792. ' Keller, Civilp. 20. « Gains, iv. 19. Digitized by Microsoft® DEVELOPMENT OF OONDICTIO. 105 ea res est, tantam pecuniam, index, iV™ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. (c) Condictio incerti. The above condictio triticaria, or certae rei, was in course of time extended by the interpretation of the jurists or by the Praetor's Edict to res incertae, and gave rise to a condictio incerti, which was the proper action on a stipulation involving facere or praestare or some other object of indefinite value. The thing promised might be defined as quanti in- terest, or quanti ea lis aestimata erit etc.', and it is plain how much this comprehensive mode of ex- pression must have increased the adaptability and general usefulness of the stipulation. In this way, for instance, the cautio damni infecti and the stipu- lations of warranty were doubtless always expressed. The nature of this condictio may perhaps be best understood from its formula, which was as follows : Quod A^ Agerius de N" Negidio incertum stipulatus est, quidquid paret oh earn rem N™ Negidium A" Agerio dare facere oportere, eius iudex, N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. aJ' This was so far an advance upon the condictio certae rei that, the condemnatio here left the damages entirely to the discretion of the judge; but it was still a stricti iuris action, in which no equitable pleas were ad- mitted on the part of the defendant. {d) Actio ex stipulatu. We have seen that the condictiones certae pecuniae and certae rei were due to legislation, and the con- dictio incerti to juristic interpretation: it remains 1 Voigt, RG. I. pp. 601-2. 2 (jai. iv. 131, 136. Digitized by Microsoft® 106 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. to inquire what was the origin of the actio ex stiffulatu, i.e. the honae fidei action on a stipulation for incertwm dare or for certwm facere^, which completed this series of legal remedies. Its ap- pearance was an event of great importance to the subsequent history of Contract, since it applied ex- clusively to stipulations containing a honae fidei clausula, and it was by means of this action alone that such stipulations were enforced I Voigt's ex- planation of its origin is that the actio ex stipulatu was devised as the proper remedy for fidepromissio and for the cautio rei uxoriae introduced in A.V.C. 523'. But it is very doubtful if the date can be fixed with such exactness. There is nothing to show that the actio ex stipulatu did not exist earlier than those particular forms of stipulation ; and if it had been, as Voigt thinks, the original action on a fideproTnissio, it would probably have been known as actio ex fidepromisso or by some such descriptive name. The introduction of the doli clausula is the most important event in the whole history of the stipulatio, yet the exact moment at which this took place is hard, if not impossible, to fix. Girard* attributes its invention to C. Aquilius Gallus. But if this had been the case, Cicero^ would hardly have overlooked the fact. On the other hand Voigt, who rightly identifies the actio ex stipulatu with the action on a 1 Bethmann-Hollweg, C. P. p. 267. 2 44 Dig. 4. 4. fr. 15-16. 3 I. N. IV. 407. Gellius iv. 1, 2. * N. Rev. Hist, de Droit, xiii. 93. ^ Off. in. 14. 60. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO ACTIO EX STIPVLATV. 107 doli clausula, and regards the two as inseparable, places the introduction of doli clausula earlier than the time of Cicero, because that writer mentions the actio ex stipulatu among the " indicia in quibus ad- ditur ' ex fide bona^.' " The introduction of the first clausida doli was, according to Voigt", made by the words fides, in fidepromissio, and "quod melius aequius sit" in the cautio rei uxoriae^. This conjecture is unsupported by evidence ; for though we know that cautio rei ihxoriae* and fidepromissio^ were both actionable by the actio ex stipulatu, and therefore must have contained doli clausulae, we have no right to assume that they were the first of their kind. We cannot, moreover, follow Voigt in supposing the actio ex stipidatu to have been expressly invented for fidepromissio and cautio rei uxoriae. We have to presuppose the existence of a condictio incerti before the doli clausula could become actionable, since a claim of damages for dolus was necessarily an in- certum; and there is no reason why the actio ex stipulatu should not have been developed from the condictio incerti by mere interpretation. Its essential connection with the stipulatio containing the clausula doli may readily be admitted, but we cannot be certain what were the first stipulations containing clausulae of the kind. The doli clausidae are well summarized by Voigt '^ as follows : 1 I. N. IV. 413. 2 I. N. IV. 407. 3 Boeth. ad Top. 17. 66. " 23 Dig. 4. 26. s 45 Dig. 1. 122. « I. N. iv. 411. Digitized by Microsoft® 108 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. (i) " Quod melius aequius erit," as in " cautio rei uxoriae." (ii) " Fide," in fidepromissio. (iii) " Si quid dolo in ea re factum sit^." (iv) "DoluTn Tnalum, huic rei abesse afuturuinque esse spondesne^ ?" (v) " Gui rei si dolus malus non abest, non abfuerit, quanti ea res est tantam pecuniam, dari spondes^ ? " The date of each of these forms is, however, impossible to determine. The cases of contracts by stipulation in which doli clausulae are found have been collected by Voigt*, but need not be enumerated here. The effect of the clausula was to convert the action on the stipulation containing it from a stricti iuris action into a bonaefidei action, in which equitable defences might be entertained by the judge. This ex- pansion was effected by introducing the words " dare facer e oportere ex fide bona " in the intentio of the action. If "ex fide bona " had not appeared in the formula of an actio ex stipulatu, the action would simply have been a condictio incerti. It seems there- fore reasonable to suppose that the actio ex stipulatu was nothing more than a development of the condictio incerti, and that the words ex fide bona, perhaps suggested by the actio emti, were inserted to suit the liberal language of the stipulation. In praetorian stipulations the doli clausula was 1 4 Dig. 8. 31. ^ 46 Dig. 7. 19, 50 Dig. 16. 69. 3 46 Dig. 1. 38. fr. 13. " I. N. iv. 416 ff. Digitized by Microsoft® EXCEPTIO DOLI UNCONNECTED WITH OLA VSVLA. 109 an usual part of the fonnula; e.g. in cautio legis Falcidiae^, stipulatio iudicatum soltii', stipulatio ratam rem haberi^, etc. But in conventional stipulations it was purely a matter of choice whether the doli clausula should be inserted or not. We must not fancy that the actio de dolo and the exceptio doli, which Cicero attributes to his colleague C. Aquilius Gallus', had anything in com- mon with the actio ex stipulatu based upon a clausula doli^. The former remedies were a pro- tection against fraud where no agreement of a contrary kind had been made", whereas the action on a stipulation containing the clausula doli was available only when dolus maltts had been specially excluded by agreement. Hence it follows that where the stipulation had omitted the clausula doli there can have been no remedy for dolus until the great reform introduced by Aquilius Gallus. As soon as stipulations of all kinds had thus become actionable, and had probably passed out of the hands of the Pontiffs into the far more popular jurisdiction of the Praetor, the law of contract received an extraordinary stimulus, and we find the stipulation producing entirely new varieties of obli- gation, though its form in each kind of contract re- mained of course substantially the same. Here are some of the purposes for which stipulatio was em- 1 35 Big. 3. 1. = 46 Big. 1. 33. » 46 Big. 8. 22. fr. 7. ' Off. in. 14. 60. Nat. B. in. 30. 74. » Voigt, I. N. 3. 319. ' See the case of Canius, in Cio. Off', in. 14. 58-60. Digitized by Microsoft® 110 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. ployed, apart from its uses in procedure and surety- ship. (1) It produced a special form of agency by means of adstipulatio^. The promisee who wished a claim of his to be satisfied at some far-off period, when he might himself be dead, had only to get a friend to join with him in receiving the stipulatory promise. This friend could then at any time prosecute the claim with as good right as the principal stipulator, and the law recognised him as agent for the latter. Even a slave could in this way stipulate on behalf of his master*. (2) In consequence of its universal adaptability, the stipulation gave rise to nmiatio. The reducing to a simple verbal obligation of some debt or obligation based upon different grounds (e.g. upon a sale, legacy, etc.) was accomplished by stipulatio, and known as expromissio debiti proprii. (3) It created a rudimentary assignability of obligations by virtue of delegatio, another form of nouatio. In the one case, the debtor was changed, and the creditor was authorised by the former debtor to stipulate from the new debtor the amount of the former debt : in the other case {expromissio debiti alieni) the creditor was changed, and the new creditor stipulated from the debtor the amount owed by him to the former creditor. (4) It also created the notion of correal obli- gation, by which two or more promisors in a stipulation made themselves jointly responsible for the whole debt, and so gave additional security to 1 Gai. III. 117. = .? Inst. 17. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® FKUITS OF 8TIPVLATI0. Ill the promisee. The effects of this will be seen in a later section. (5) It served to embody in a convenient shape any special condition annexed to a separate contract — e.g. a promise to pay the price agreed upon in a sale', and the stipulationes simplae et duplae annexed to sales of res nee mancipi^. Thus an enforceable contractus adiectus could be made on the analogy of a pactum adiectum. (6) It clothed in an actionable form so many different kinds of agreements that it would be impossible to exhaust the list. For instance, agree- ments as to interest^ wagers, the promise of a dowry^, the making of a compromise^ the creation of an usufruct, could all be thrown into stipulations either single or reciprocal, and thus turned into binding obligations. (7) Most of the events in the history of this immense development of stipulatio are impossible to fix at any given period, though the attempt to do so has been often made. Yet the invention of one famous stipulation can be exactly dated, from its bearing the name of Cicero's colleague, C. Aquilius Gallus, and having therefore been invented by him in the year of his Praetorship^. This Aquilian formula, which operated as a general release of all obligations, and which the Institutes' give us in full, is an excellent instance of the usefulness of the stipulation, and it also clearly shows what long and 1 Cato, R. R. 146. ^ Varro, R. R. ii. 3. ' Plant. Most. 3. 1. 101. * See p. 32. « Plant. Bacch. 4. 8. 76. « A.v.c. 688. ' 3 Inst. 29. 2. Digitized by Microsoft® 112 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. elaborate forms this contract sometimes assumed in later times, so that all kinds of terms, de- scriptions or warranties might without difficulty be incorporated in a single comprehensive formula. It was probably this increasing length of stipu- lations which caused them to be put in writing, and induced lawyers to publish formulae in which they should be expressed. Both of these results had already taken place in the time of Cicero. He not only speaks of written stipulations, but also describes the composition of stipulatory formulae as one of the chief literary occupations of a leading lawyer'. We know from a constitution of the Emperor Leo, which changed the law in this respect, that the written stipulations of the Republic and early Empire were merely put into writing for the sake of evidence". The writing in itself constituted no contract, and raised no presumption in favour of the existence of a contract; but the written stipu- lation had to conform with all the rules of the ordinary spoken stipulation, since it was nothing but a spoken stipulation recorded in writing. The legislative changes of the period were mostly devoted to modifications in the stipulations of suretyship. But in a few cases the ordinary stipu- lation was itself affected. (i) By the Lex Titia of A.v.c. 416—426° stipu- lations for the payment of money lost at gambling were declared void. (ii) Various laws against usury were enacted, 1 de leg. i. 4. 14. 2 3 Inst. 15. 1. ' Voigt in Phil. Hist. Ber. der S. G. der W. xiii. 257. Digitized by Microsoft® SPONSIO IN PROCEDURE. 113 all of which affected the stipulation, since that was the mode in which fenus was usually contracted. (ui) The Lex Cinaia de mwieribus of A. v. c. 550, the object of which was to restrain lavish gifts to pleaders and public men, naturally limited all stipu- lations between parties within range of the prohibi- tion, and in the corresponding condictio gave rise to the exceptio legis Ginciae, which probably ran thus : ...si in ea re nihil contra legem Ginciam factum sit... (iv) The Praetor C. Aquilius Gallus, as above mentioned^, instituted in his Edict the exceptio doli mali, and thereby nullified stipulations which, how- ever perfect ia form, had been procured by fraud. This exceptio was of course inapplicable to cases in which the stipulation contained a clausula doli. II. Sponsio in the law of Procedure. The original function of the processual sponsio seems to have been that of helping to decide the question at issue by expressing it in the form of a wager. As a common feature of practice, sponsio made its appearance in many other different connec- tions, and sometimes developed into the more modern stipulatio. We find it employed : (i) As a means of obtaining a decision by a wager, in which the contention of either party was succinctly stated and so submitted to the judge. This was known as sponsio praeitodicialis. (ii) As a means of fixing a penalty, as well as of obtaining a decision, in (a) the condictio certae 1 p. 109. B. E. 8 Digitized by Microsoft® 114 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. pecuniae or (6) the interdicts, in which case it was known as sponsio poenalis. (iii) As a mode of giving security ; for instance in the uindicatio, where we find the stipulatio pro praede litis et uindiciarum. Bekker's classification^ does not exactly correspond with this one. He divides processual sponsiones into (A) sponsiones made in the course of a trial, (a) as to the chief question, (6) as to conditions and incidental matters, and (B) sponsiones made apart from a trial, (a) with a view to some future trial, (b) with no such view. The objection to this classification seems to be that the whole of class (B) were not properly pro- cessual sponsiones at all. 1. Sponsio praeiudicialis' was a promise to pay a fixed sum, made by the plaintiff to the defendant, and conditioned upon the plaintiff's defeat. It was accompanied by a similar promise (restipulatio) on the part of the defendant, conditioned upon his defeat. These mutual sponsiones were in fact nothing more than a bet on the result of the action. They generally involved a merely nominal sum, and were perhaps first introduced in the actio per sponsionem in rem, as a means of settling the question of ownership without employing the larger and more costly sacramentum of five hundred asses'. The date of their origin is impossible to fix, but the custom of making such sponsiones and having them decided by a judge 1 Akt. I. 257. 2 Gai. iv. 94. 165. 3 Baron, p. 403. Digitized by Microsoft® SPONSIO PRAEIVDIGIALIS. 115 seems to have been one of great antiquity, and must have existed long before the sponsio became armed with any condictio. The very notion of a bet submitted to a judge as a means of deciding rights of property seems, as Sir Henry Maine has said ', to savour of the primitive time when the judge was simply a man of wisdom called in to arbitrate between two disputants. Moreover, it is hard to imagine that the actio per sponsionem in rem could have been introduced in any but the most ancient times, when in Cicero's age there were the rei uindicatio sacramento and the far simpler m uin- dicatio per formulam petitoriam to accomplish the same objects There is therefore every probability that the actio per sponsionem was at least as old as the legis actio sacramento. According to Voigt* the procedure per sponsionem was the original form also of the actio Publiciana introduced in A.v.C. 519. In Cicero's time it was still a favorite method of pro- cedure for all sorts of litigation^. (a) In questions as to property the plaintiff might choose whether he preferred to bring an actio per formfublam, petitoriam, or one per sponsionem^. If he chose the latter course, the defendant was compelled sponsions se defenders. (b) In really trivial praeiitdicia the question was stated in the formula and sent straight to the i^tdex without any condemnation, but the procedure 1 E.H. of I. 259. 2 KeUer, C. P. § 28. ^ j. j^. ly. 506. " e.g. Caec. 8. 5 Lex Ruhr. e. 21, 22; Cic. 2 Verr. i. 45. 115; Gaius, iv. 91. ^ Gai. IV. 44. 8—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 116 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. in this case was not necessarily based upon a sponsio praeiudicialis and might be a simple preliminary inquiry ordered by the Praetor. The sponsio praeiudidalis thus worked in a peculiarly roundabout way; its penalty was nomi- nal and not therefore its real object, and it brought about a decision on the main question by treat- ing that question as a thing of secondary im- portance. 2. Sponsio poenalis (a) in the condictio, was pecu- liar to the legis actio per condictionem introduced by the Lex Silia. It was accompanied by a restipulatio, so that either party to the action promised to the other a penalty of one-third ' in the event of losing his case. Eudorff" reconstructs the formula of this sponsio as follows : Si pecuniam certam creditam qua de re agitur mihi debes, earn pecuniam cum tertia parte amplius dare spondes? But this seems in- correct, since from Cicero's language' we gather that the sponsio was for the tertia pars only; the sum in dispute plus one-third is never mentioned. The formula then was probably as follows: Si pecuniam certam creditam qua de agitur mihi debes, dus pecuniae tertiam partem dare spondes ? Hence Rudorff* seems also wrong in stating that the con- demnatio of the formula in the corresponding condictio must have involved the principal sum plus one-third. Voigt ^ more correctly holds that the condemnatio can only have involved the summa sponsionis. We can 1 Cic. Base. Com. 5. 14. 2 Ed. Perp. p. 103. '' " legititnae partis sponsio facta est." Rose. Com. 4. 10. * Rom. RG. II. 142. ^ j_ j^ m 741^ Digitized by Microsoft® SPON^SIO POENALIS. 117 see that, as Gains '■ implies, this sponsio was just as much praeiudicialis as that of the actio per sponsio- nem, giving as it did a ground for the decision of the main question ; but it was also distinctly poenalis, be- cause the sum which it involved was worth having and worth extorting from the unsuccessful party, and therefore the condemnatio was carried out in the usual manner. The principal sum in dispute was then no doubt quietly paid, since the decision as to the sponsio tertiae partis had also settled to whom the disputed sum belonged. (b) In the private interdicts (possessoria and restitutoria) if the party to whom the interdict was addressed chose to dispute it, he might do so by challenging the plaintiff to make a sponsio and restipulatio, the rights of which should be deter- mined by recuperatores. This sponsio differed from the former (1) by being purely poenalis and having no trace of praeiudicium for its object ; (2) by being in factwm concepta ^. The origin of these two uses of sponsio cannot be dated, in the case of (a) because we do not know the date of the Lex Silia, and in the case of (6) because we do not know when the possessory interdict was first granted by the Praetor. But it is fairly certain that the sponsio poenalis of the interdict was more modern than the sponsio poenalis of the condictio, partly because it had no sort of connection with a praeiudicium, which seems to have been the original object of the processual sponsio, and partly because it was in factum concepta. 1 IV. 93, 94. 2 Gai. iv. 166; Cic. Caec, 8. 23. Digitized by Microsoft® 118 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. 3. Another purpose for which the sponsio was adopted in procedure was to give bond against pos- sible losses. It thus furnished a substitute for the old form of obligation contracted by the praes in real actions. The stipulatio pro praede litis et uindi- ciarum, accompanied by sureties ', was given by the plaintiff who wished to bring an actio per sponsionem in rem, or who disputed an interdict, and the amount promised in the stipulation was double the value of the property in dispute. Another contract of the same kind was the stipulatio ivdicatum solui ', by which the plaintiff in an actio per formulam petitoriam obtained a promise from the defendant that he would pay up the value of the property in dispute and of its fructus, in the event of being defeated in the action. Voigt gives imaginary formulae for these two stipulations", but in reality we do not know much about them. Stipulations of this kind were not peculiar to the law of procedure. They were simply varieties of the cautio, a very common method of securing future rights, and they had their counter- part in the cautio damni infecti, cautio Muciatm, cautio legis Falcidiae and all the praetorian stipula- tions. The origin of the cautiones in general cannot however be dated : we know merely that they must have been invented subsequently to the introduction of the condictio. III. Sponsio as a means of Suretyship. The introduction of the new idea of correal obli- 1 Cic. 2 Verr. i. 45. 115; Gai. iv. 91-94. 2 46 Dig. 7. 20 ; Gai. rr. 89. ' Im Nat. in. 588 and 820. Digitized by Microsoft® SPOJfSIO IN SURETYSHIP. 119 gation which resulted from the use of the stipulation, naturally led to the use of the stipulation as a mode of suretyship. For if three sponsores promised the same sum to the same stipulator, the latter obviously had three times as good security as if he had put his question to one sponsor instead of to three. 1. The consequence was that sponsor soon acquired the special meaning of a co-promisor or surety, and this change probably took place soon after the sponsio became actionable by the Lex Silia. But if the surety -sponsor had had no recourse against the principal-spojisor whose debt he had been com- pelled to satisfj"^, his case would have been hard indeed. To provide against this hardship, the Lex Publilia ' of A. V. c. 427 enacted : (a) That the surety-spo?iso?' might make use of an actio depensi against the principal debtor for the amount spent on his behalf (6) That the mode of procedure in this actio depensi should be the legis actio per manus iniec- tionem, and that the penalty should be duplum^. (c) That the principal debtor should however have six months' grace for the repayment of his surety, but (d) That a surety who paid a gambling-debt on behalf of his principal should forfeit his right of action. This law is alluded to by Plautus, and was clearly prior to the introduction of fidepromissio. 1 Voigt in Phil. Hist. Ber. der k. s. Ges. d. Wiss. xlii. p. 259. 2 Gai. IV. 22. 171. Digitized by Microsoft® 120 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. In later times the surety had in the actio mandati a further remedy against the principal sponsor. 2. About the beginning of the fifth century, as new forms of stipulatio grew up alongside of the old sponsio, another sort of suretyship was introduced under the name oi fidepromissio. It was so called because the sureties entered into a stipulation con- taining the words : "Jide tua promittis ? fide mea pro- mitto." The new form was no doubt devised for the benefit of foreigners and marked the further growth of ius gentium. It seems to have been treated as exactly equivalent to sponsio, for sponsio as well as fidepromissio could only be used to secure a verbal obligation \ Since it is coupled with sponsio in the Lex Apideia, and since the heirs of sponsores and fidepromissores were both alike free from the obliga- tion of their predecessors ^ it is fairly certain that the actio depensi and inanus iniectio of the Leoo Publilia must have been extended to fidepromissio by interpretation '. The fidepromissor also had the remedy of the actio mandati, but this was of later origin. The Lex Apuleia de sponsoribus et fide promis- soribus of A.v.C. 525 ^ applying to both Italy and the provinces, gave to any sponsor or fidepromissor who had paid more than his aliquot share of the principal debt a right to bring the severe actio depensi against each of his co-promisors to recover the amount overpaid. This law, giving as it did protection to the sponsor against his co-sponsor, was ' Gai. III. 119 ; iv. 137. 2 Gai. in. 120. ' Gai. III. 127. " Voigt, I. N. iv. 424. Digitized by Microsoft® FIDEPROMISSIO. 121 the natural complement to the Lex Puhlilia which had already secured him against the principal debtor. The object of the next law, Lex Furia de sponso- ribus et fidepromissoribus of A.V.c. 536 \ is rather obscure, but it seems to have re-enacted the Lex Apuleia with reference to Italy only, and probably provided the spmisor with a more thorough mode of redress. What this mode was the language of Gains ^ does not make plain ; but Moyle is no doubt wrong in asserting ' that it was the actio pro socio, unmis- takably of much later origin. Its only clearly new enactment was that sponsores or fidepromissores in Italy, whose guarantee was for an unlimited period, should be liable for two years only. This limited liability Voigt thinks was perhaps borrowed from the rules applying to the uas. Lastly, the Lex Cicereia (Studemund) of uncertain date, but which must have been passed before A.V.c. 620, since it ignored fideiussio, gave further protection to sureties by enacting : (<x) That any creditor who secured his debt by taking sponsores or fidepromissores must announce the amount of the debt and the number of the sureties before they gave their adpromissio. (b) If he failed to do this, any surety might within 30 days institute a praeiudicium to inquire into his conduct ; and if the judge declared that the required announcement had not been made, all the sureties were freed from their liability*. This law 1 L. Furius Philue was Praetor in that year. Voigt, I. N. iv. 424. 2 ni. 122. 2 Inst. p. 411, note. * Gai. iii. 123. Digitized by Microsoft® 122 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. was subsequently, we know, extended by interpreta- tion to fideiussores. 3. A third form of suretyship was at last de- vised, by which obligations other than verbal ones could be similarly secured. This was done by a stipulation containing the words "fide tua ivbes ? fide mea ivheo" and it was hence known as fideiussio. It must have been iuvented about the beginning of the sixth century, and was doubtless needed, as Voigt suggests^, in order to provide a form of suretyship for the newly invented real and consensual con- tracts ". Its chief points of difference from the other two forms were that (a) it applied to all kinds of contractual obligations ; (6) the heir of the fideiussor was bound by the same obligation as his predecessor ; and (c) the provisions of the foregoing legislation as to sponsio and fidepromissio did not as a rule apply to fideiussio. The only point of resemblance was that the fideiussor, like the sponsor and fidepro- missor, had the actio mandati^ against his principal, whereas the sponsor and probably the fidepromissor had the actio depensi of the Lex Puhlilia in addition to the more modem remedy. The Lex Cornelia mentioned by Gains * as affect- ing all sureties alike, whether sponsores, fidepromis- sores or fideiussores, has been shown by Voigt ' to be a part of the Lex Cornelia swmtuaria of A.V.C. 673. Two sections of this act provided : (i) That no surety should validly become re- 1 I. N. IV. 425. 2 Gai. ni. 119. » Gai. m. 127. » in. 124. ° Phil. Hist. Ber. der k. s. Ges. der Wiss. xlii. p. 280. Digitized by Microsoft® BXPMNSILA TIO. 123 sponsible for more than two million sesterces > on behalf of the same person in any given year. Except in the case of dos^, whatever liability was contracted over and above that amount was void. (ii) That no suretyship of any sort should be valid when given for a gambling debt I In thus tabulating all the laws on this subject, we must not omit to mention the rule applying to all forms of suretyship alike, that if the surety had guaranteed a lesser sum than the principal debt, his guarantee held good, but if a larger sum or a differ- ent thing, the guarantee became void. In conclusion, it is very remarkable how largely the law of suretyship was developed by means of legislation. The reason was, that while sufficient means existed for enforcing the mutual obligations of debtor and creditor, there were no rules to regulate the relations of debtor and surety, or of sureties among one another. The old uadimonium was ap- parently inadequate, while the newer uadimonium, as we saw, was but a form of stipulatio, and the ordinary condictio would clearly have been inapplic- able to cases of this kind. Hence it became neces- sary that legislation should intervene. Art. 3. EXPENSILATIO. So many irreconcilable statements have been made as to the nature of this peculiarly Roman contract" that no one can hope to describe it with perfect accuracy. Confident 1 20,000 according to Dauz, B. BG. ii. 83. 2 Gai. m. 124-5. ^ Voigt, Bom. BO. i. 616. * See a full summary of the various opinions in Danz, B. BG. II. pp. 43-60. Digitized by Microsoft® 124 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. assertions on the subject serve only to show our real ignorance, and ignorant we must be, owing to the vagueness of the evidence. Yet it is only as to the form of the contract that much controversy has prevailed. Its operation and its history are tolerably certain. Form: Our ignorance respecting the mode in which the contract was made is partly due to the fact that tabulae, which meant account-books in general, meant also a chirograph, or a written stipulation, or an ordinary note-book'. We can never be quite sure in what sense a technical term of such ambiguity is used in any given passage. Everyone agrees that the entry of a debt in the creditor's account-book imposed a correspbnding obligation upon the debtor, and the theory that debts were entered for this purpose in separate documents has been exploded ever since Savigny''' refuted it. But the question so difficult to answer is this : what sort of account-book was the codex in which these binding entries were made ? We gather from Cicero's speech for Roscius the actor that there were in his day at least two principal books in general use, (1) aduersaria ', and (2) codex or tabulae rationwm. The former was a day-book, in which the details of every-day business were jotted down, while the latter was a carefully kept ledger, containing a summary of the household receipts and expenditure, copied at regular intervals from the aduersaria. These two 1 See Wunderlich, Liu. oblig. p. 19. s Verm. Schrif. i. 211 ff. ' Also called ephemeris. Prop. iii. 23. 20. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES OF BOOK-KEEPING. 125 books were also used by bankers (argentarii) ; and in their codew or ledger were entered their accounts- current with their different customers '. Similarly in the codex of the householder there were probably separate accounts, on separate folios, under such heads as ratio praedii, ratio locitlorum, &c.^ There was sometimes used a book known as (3) kalendanum, in which the interest on loans was computed and entered ', the making of loans at interest being hence called kalendarium exercere. (a) Some writers are of opinion that these book -debts were entered by the creditor in the main codex, and that this codex was a mere cash-book. In that case, unless the debt was a loan actually paid in cash, it must have been entered on both sides of the account, debtor as well as creditor, otherwise the book would not have balanced. This twofold entry is said to have been called transcriptio; and nomen transcripticium would accordingly have been the name applied to an}' debt contracted in that manner. The weakness of this theory lies in the clumsiness of the alleged twofold method of entry; we can scarcely believe that an imaginary receipt would have been credited in the account simply for the purpose of making both sides balance. More- over it is unwise to assume, as these writers do in support of their theory, that the Roman method of keeping accounts was an easy matter and therefore needed but few books ; for in a large town house, or on a large estate with bailiffs, tenants and slaves to 1 2 Big. 13. 10 and 2 Dig. 14. 47. - 33 Dig. 8. 23. 3 12 Dig. 1. 41 and 33 Dig. 8. 23. Digitized by Microsoft® 126 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. be provided for, it seems far more likely that the accounts should have been elaborate and the account- books numerous. (6) According to Voigt, book-debts (nomina) were entered in a (4) codex accepti et expensi kept for the express purpose. Whether such a fourth book existed, or whether the rationes accepti et eccpensi were kept as a separate account in the main codex rationum, is a question which our authorities hardly enable us to answer. This does not however seem very important, and it is certainly impossible to tell in any given passage whether the author is speaking of the main codex (2), or of the codex accepti et expensi (4), which Voigt supposes to have been a distinct book. His theory is plausible, for codex accepti et expensi would be a very natural name for a book containing only expensa lata and accepta lata. But we may fairly doubt the existence of this fourth book, partly be- cause there is no passage which clearly distinguishes it from the other account-books, and partly because it is hard to see why the books of a Roman house- hold, though clearly numerous, should have been thus needlessly multiplied. Why should not 'no- mina facere'-' have meant " to open an account" with a man, and why could not such an account have been opened as well on a folio of the prin- cipal ledger as on a folio of the imaginary codex accepti et expensi ? Perhaps a banker may have found it worth his while to keep, as Voigt supposes, a separate book for his loans and book-debts, but we 1 Cic. 2 Verr. i. 36. 92 ; Seneca, Ben. in. 15. Digitized by Microsoft® NATURE OF TRANSCRIPTIO. 127 cannot imagine that this would have been the common practice of ordinary householders, when their codex would have done equally well. Eaypensilatio was the name of the transaction, while the entry itself was called nomen; and the term nomen transcripticium, which has been ex- plained as the equivalent of nomen, because the entry was transcribed from the aduersaria into the codex, or because it was copied into both sides of the account, seems rather to have denoted only a nomen of a novatory character'. That nomen could produce an original obligation is proved by the cases of Visel- lius Varro" and of Canius' in which there is no mention of transcriptio. Further Gaius clearly im- pKes* that the nomen transcripticium was but one instance of the use of expensilatio, and the cases cited by him are purely novatory. Voigt therefore is probably right in distinguishing the ordinary nomen which created an obligation, from the nomen transcripticium, which novated an obligation already existent. If so, the name transcripticium comes from the fact that (a) a debt entered in one place as owed by Titius might be transcribed into another part of the codex as owed by Negidius (transcriptio a persona in per- sonam), or (h) a debt owed by Negidius, on account of (e.g.) a sale, might be embodied in an expensilatio and thus converted from a honae fidei into a stricti iuris 1 See Gaius in. 128. ^ Val. Max. vni. 2. 2. ^ Cic. Off. III. 14. 59. * " ueluti nominibus transcripticiis ," in. 130. Digitized by Microsoft® 128 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. obligation by being entered in the codex {transcriptio a re in personam). Some passages are supposed to describe the entry of book-debts in the books not only of the debtor and creditor, but of third persons also' ; but it is difficult to imagine that any man would have entered in the midst of his own accounts a record of transactions which did not actually concern him. Here again we may believe that the ambiguity of the word tabulue has led the commentators astray. What they have taken for the account-books of a third party may have meant simply his memorandum or note-book. Salpius^ has endeavoured to explain away the difficulty by asserting that these tabulae of third parties really mean in every instance the tabulae of either debtor or creditor. But the passages do not seem to be capable of bearing such an interpretation, and it appears far more likely that the word tabulae has caused all the difficulty. To summarise then this view of the Literal Contract, we may believe it to have been made by an entry written by the creditor on a separate folio of the codex (2) or chief household ledger, and that its form was very probably that given by Voigt' as follows : "HS X a Numerio Negidio promissa tfcc. expen- sa Numerio Negidio fero in diem " ; whereupon the debtor might, if he liked, make this corresponding entry in his codex: "HS X Aulo Agerio promissa Jkc, Aulo Agerio refero in diem,." 1 E.g. Cio. Att. IV. 18; Rose. Com. i.l; de Or. ii. 69. 280. 2 Novation, p. 95. 3 Bam. BG. i. 64. Digitized by Microsoft® FOKM OF ENTRY. 129 In cases of novation, the form would be as follows : Creditor: "HS X a Lucio Titio dehita expensa Numerio Negidio fero in diem" (transcriptio apersona in personam), or else : "HS X a Numerio Negidio ex emti causa dehita expensa Numerio Negidio fero in diem," {transcriptio a re in personam). As in the previous case, the debtor might make similar entries in his codex. Having thus opened an account, which could only be done with the authorisation of the debtor, the creditor would naturally enter on the same page such items as payment of interest on the debt, payment of the principal on account, &c. According to Voigt, the entries showing repayment of the principal would be made in the following form : "HS X a Numerio Negidio dehita accepta Numerio Negidio fero." Such an entry constituted a valid release and went by the name of acceptilatio. Voigt' thinks that the acceptilatio, as here given, was made first by the debtor, and that the creditor followed him with a corresponding accepti relatio. But the word acceptum seems rather to imply that the release was looked upon from the creditor's point of view. It is therefore more likely to have been the creditor who took the initiative in entering the acceptilatio, just as he did in enteiing the expensilatio, while the debtor perhaps followed him with an accepti relatio. We know from Cicero^ that expensilatio could be used to create an original obligation, while Gaius tells us that it was much used for making an assign- ment or a novation. Where however a loan made in 1 ib. p. 65. 2 Off. III. 14. 58-60. B. E. 9 Digitized by Microsoft® 130 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. cash was entered in the creditor's book, the contract was regarded as a case not of expensilatio but of mutuum, and the entry was called nomen arcarium}. This name seems to have come from the fact that the money was actually drawn from the area or money-chest^; and in such case the entry on the creditor's books constituted no fresh obligation, but served merely as evidence of the mutuum,. History: The old theory of its origin, given by Savigny and Sir Henry Maine, is that ecopensilaiio was a simplified form of neacum. They argued that the word expensum pointed clearly to the fiction of a money -loan made by weight. But they never succeeded in explaining how it happened that the nexal loan should have produced a contract so strangely difierent from itself. The newer theory, which Voigt has ably set forth ^ is far more intelligible and agrees with all the facts. Its merit lies in recognising expensilatio as a device first used by bankers and merchants and subsequently adopted by the rest of the com- munity. Nothing indeed could be plainer than the commercial origin of expensilatio. Like the negoti- able instrument of modem times it is a striking instance of the extent to which Trade has moulded the Law of Contract. This institution probably did not originate at Rome, but the Greek bankers of Southern Italy may have adopted and used it centuries before we hear of its existence. It seems to have been first iatroduced* by the Greek argen- 1 Gaius in. 131. ••' Cic. Top. 3. 16. 3 Z. N. II. 244 ft. * Voigt, mm. RG. i. 60. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF EXPENSILATIO. 131 torn or tarpezitae (TpaTre^Tai), who came to Rome about A. V. c. 410 — 440, and took the seven shops known as tabernae ueteres^ on the East side of the Porum^ Their numbers were subsequently increased, when the tabernae nouae were also occupied by them. Their business was extremely varied and their system of book-keeping doubtless highly developed. They made loans^, received deposits*, cashed cheques {perscriptionesY, managed auctions', and exchanged foreign monies for a commission (collybusy. They also used codices accepti et expensi, in which, as we have seen, accounts-current were kept with their customers ^ We learn from Livy' that by A. v. C. 5.59 the expensilatio thus introduced by them had become a common transaction among private in- dividuals. It cannot have been long before the conception of pecunia credita was extended so as to cover book-debts as well as stipulations ; but we do not know the exact date. From Cicero" however we learn that pecunia expensa lata was a branch of pecunia credita within the scope of the Lex Silia, and that the proper remedy for its enforcement was the condictio certae pecuniae with its sponsio tertiae partis. As Voigt" has well pointed out, the expensilatio presupposes the exis- tence throughout the community of a high standard of good faith. It was therefore ill adapted for ' Liu. XXVI. 27. 2 Liu. vii. 21. 3 Plaut. Cure. 5. 2. 20. * ib. 2. 3. 66. 5 ib. 3. 62-65. « Cio. Caec. 6. 16. ? Cio. Att. XII. 6. 1. 8 2 Dig. 14. 47. ^ Liu. XXXV. 7. ^'' Rose. Com. 5. 14. 11 I. N. II. 420. 9—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 132 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. general use among the Greeks, whose bad faith was proverbial'. The fact that it was at Rome, and at Rome only, that this contract received full legal recognition, is proved by Gains' doubts" as to whether a peregrin could be bound by a nomen transcripticiwn. By the end of the Republic eocpen- silatio was at its height of favour, but it died out, except among bankers, soon after the time of Gains, for in Justinian's day it was unknown. Art. 4. Chirographvm and Stngrapha were forms of written contract borrowed, as their name implies, from Greek custom, and chiefly used by pere- grins, as Gaius informs us°. The distinction between the two was purely formal, the one being signed by the debtor (cAiro^rrop/i Mm), and the other being written out in duplicate, signed by both parties, and kept by each of them (syngraphay. These foreign instru- ments at first produced nothing more than a pactum nudrmi, for wherever we find syngrapha mentioned in Plautus, it denotes a mere agreement (pactum), the terms of which had been committed to writing and which was certainly not actionable, while chiro- graphum, never occurs in his plays. The Roman magistrates, finding these instruments recognised by aliens, ventured at length to enforce debts ew syn- grapha, and thus their legal validity was secured^ They had received, some sort of recognition by the 1 Plaut. Asin. 1. 3. 47. ■" m. 133. s III. 134. * See Diet, thirteenth cent, in Heimbach, Greditum p. 520, and Ascon. in Gic. Verr. i. 36. s Cic. pro Rah. Post. 3. 6; Har. resp. 13. 29 ; Phil. ii. 37. 95 ; ad Att. Yi. 1. 15 ; ii. v. 21. 10 ; ib. vi. 2. 7. Digitized by Microsoft® CHIROGRAPHVM. 133 time of Cicero, but when they were first enforced does not appear, though it was certainly late in the history of the Republic. Gneist^ has advanced the theory that in Cicero's time neither chirographum nor syngrapha was a genuine literal contract, but only a document attesting the fact of a loan, which could always be rebutted by evidence aliunde. This theory is the more plausible because Gains himself does not seem certain as to the binding nature of these documents^ An interesting passage in Theophilus° is some- times said to give the form in which litterarum obligatio proper, i.e. expensilatio, was contracted. This view is certainly wrong, for the context shows that Theophilus meant to describe a contract signed by the creditor and known as chirographum. As a sample of how chirographa were made, the Latin translation of this instrument may therefore be quoted : " Centum aureos quos mihi ex caussa locationis dehes tu ex conuentione et confessione lit- terarum tuanrni dabis?" And to this the debtor wrote the following answer: "Ex conuentione deheo litterarum nuearutn." This was evidently not a nomen transcripticium, but a chirographum or syngrapha, since Gaius expressly states debere se aut daturum se scribere to be the usual phraseology of such instruments. Both parties also seem here to have been present, whereas one of the chief advantages of expensilatio was that it enabled debts (by expensi- latio) and assignments (by transcriptio) to be validly made without requiring the presence of the parties 1 Form. Vertr. p. 113. ' in. 134. » Paraphr. in. 21. Digitized by Microsoft® 134 FORMAL CONTRACTS OF THE LATER REPUBLIC. concerned. Heimbach* is therefore wrong in taking the above passage as equivalent to " Eacpensos tiM tuli ?" " Expensos mihi tulisti." The transaction was evidently dififerent from expensilatio, and can have been nothing else than a dhirographtim. Another specimen chirographum preserved in the Digest^ shows that the promise or acknowledgement was sometimes made in a letter from the debtor to the creditor. > Cred. p. 330. 2 2 Dig. 14. 47. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER VI. CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. Part I. Consensual Contracts. Art. 1. Emtio Venditio. The forms of con- tract hitherto examined have been distinguished from most of the contracts of modern law in one or more of the following respects : (i) They were confined to Roman citizens. (ii) They were unilateral. (iii) They were capable of imposing obligations only by virtue of some particular formality. (iv) They were available only inter praesentes. The contract which we are now about to consider was modem in all its aspects : (i) It was open to aliens as well as to citizens. (ii) It was bi-lateral. (iii) It rested only upon the consent of the parties, required no formality, and could be re- solved like any modem contract into a proposal by one party' which became a contract when accepted by the other party. 1 Plant. Epid. 3. 4. 35. Digitized by Microsoft® 136 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS OENTIVM. (iv) It could be made at any distance, provided the parties clearly understood one another's meaning. How then can the formal contracts of the older law ever have produced such a modem institution to all outward appearance as the consensual contract of sale? The elements which make up the popular con- ception of sale are usually fourfold ; they consist of: (1) The agreement by which buyer and seller determine to exchange the wares of the latter for the money of the former; (2) The transfer of the wares from the seller to the buyer ; (3) The pajrment of the price by the buyer to the seller ; (4) The representation, express or implied, of the seller to the buyer, that his wares are as good in point of quantity or quality as they are understood to be. Mandpatio was at first a combination of the second and third elements above-mentioned. It was a transfer of ownership followed by an imme- diate payment of the price. Subsequently, as we saw, the payment became separated from the trans- fer, so that mancipatio represented only the second element. The fourth element, that of warranty, existed to a certain extent in those sales in which the transfer of property was made by moundpatio, and this fourth element we shall consider further in a later section. But throughout the early history of Rome the first element, indispensable wherever a sale of any kind takes place, was completely un- Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF ACTIO EMTI. 137 recognised by the law. The reason is that the preliminary agreement between buyer and seller was nothing more than a pactum, an agreement without legal force because usually without form. The parties might always of course embody their agreement of sale in a sponsio and restipulatio, but in such a case all that the law would recognise would be the re- ciprocal sponsiones, not the agreement itself Why, we may ask, was recognition ever accorded to this preliminary pactum ? In other words, what was the origin of emtio uenditio, which turned the pactum into a contract ? Bekker's plausible theory' adopted by Muirhead" is that contracts of sale were originally entered into by means of reciprocal stipulations, and that the actio emti was but a modification of the actio ex stipu- latu founded on those stipulations, while it borrowed from the actio ex stipulatu its characteristic bonae fidei clause. But how then did the notion of bona fides arise in the actio ex stipulatu itself? Bekker seems to have put the cart before the horse, and Mommsen" holds the far more reasonable view that the actio emti was the original agency by which bona fides found its way into the law of contract, in which case the actio ex stipulatu must have been not the prototype but the copy of the actio emti. The origin of the actio emti was indeed very curious, since it seems clearly to have been suggested and moulded by the influence of public law. The sales of public property, which used at first to be 1 Akt. I. 158. ^ Bom. Law, p. 334. 3 Z. der Sav. Stift. R. A. yi. 265. Digitized by Microsoft® 138 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS OENTIVM. carried out by the Consuls and afterwards by the Quaestors', became increasingly frequent as the conquests of Rome were multiplied, and as the supplies of booty, slaves and conquered lands be- came more and more plentifiTl. The purchase by the State of materials and military supplies was also of frequent occurrence, as the wealth of Rome increased. Now these public emtiones and iiendi- tiones constantly occurring between private citizens and the State were founded upon agreements neces- sarily formless. The State could clearly not make a iusiurandum or a sponsio, but the agreements to which the State was a party (according to the fundamental principle laid down at the beginning of this inquiry that the sanction of publicity was as strong as that of religion) were no less binding than the formal contracts of private law. A public breach of bona fides would have been notorious and dis- graceful. Whenever therefore the State took part in emtio uenditio, the agreement of sale was thereby invested with peculiar solemnity ; and thus in course of time the pactum uenditionis became so common as an inviolable contract that the actio emti uenditi was created in order to extend the force of the public eTTitio uenditio into the realm of private law. As soon as this action was provided, emtio uenditio became a regular contract, which was necessarily bilateral because performance of some sort was required from both parties. An action could thus be brought either by the buyer against a seller who refused to deliver (actio emti), or by the ^ MommseD, Z. der Sav. Stift. E. A. vi. p. 262. Digitized by Microsoft® INFLUENCE OF PUBLIC SALES. 139 seller against a buyer who failed to pay {actio uenditi). The history of the words emere uendere is in- structive. We can see that at first they were not strictly correlative. Vendere or uenumdare meant to sell, not in the sense of agreeing upon a price, but in the sense of transferring in return for moneys ; while eniere meant originally to take or to receive, without reference to the notion of buying''. But neither emere nor uendere was at first a technical term. Emere subsequently got the specialized sense of purchasing for money as distinct from permutare, to barter ^, but this particular shade of meaning seems like the actio to have had a public origin. The old technical expression for the purchase of goods at public sale was emtio sub hasta or sub corona, while the object of the sales was to get money for the treasury, and therefore the consideration was naturally paid by purchasers in coin. These public uenditioiies thus led to three results: 1. The agreement of sale came to the front as the element of chief importance, and as a transac- tion possessing all the validity of a contract. 2. The word emere came to denote the act of, buying for money, as distinct from permutatio which meant buying in kind. 3. The uenditio of public law resting wholly upon consent, which was probably signified by a lifting up of the hand in the act of bidding*, and being necessarily a transaction bonae fidei, it follows that when emtio ^ Voigt, I. N. IV. 519. ^ Paul. Diac. s. u. emere. 2 21 Dig. 1. 19. fr. 5. * Cf. the word manceps. Digitized by Microsoft® 140 CONTRACTS OF THE lYS GENTIVM. uenditio was made actionable in private law, consent was the only thing required to make the contract perfectly binding, and that the rules applicable to it were those, not of iiis strictwm, but of bona fides. The complete recognition of emMo uenditio was only attained by degrees. The first step in that direction seems to have been the granting of an exceptio rei uenditae et traditae to a defendant challenged in the possession of a thing which he had honestly obtained by purchase and delivery. The second step was the introduction of the actio Puhli- ciana, through which a plaintiff, deprived of the possession of a thing that had been sold and de- livered to him (1) by the owner or (2) by one whom he honestly believed to be the owner, might recover it by the fiction of usucapio^. These remedies, the exceptio and the actio, were necessary complements to one another. The former was a defensive, the latter an offensive weapon, and they both served to protect a bona fide purchaser who had by fair means obtained possession of an object to which in strict law another might lay • claim. The exceptio rei uenditae et traditae^ was founded upon an Edict worded somewhat as follows : SI QVIS ID QVOD VENDIDIT ET TRADIDIT NONDVM VSVCAPTVM PETET, EXCEPTIONEM DABO ^ ; and in the formula of an action by the seller to recover the thing sold this exceptio would have been introduced thus:... si non earn rem qua de agitur J.' Agerius 1 Gai. IV. 36. 2 44 j)ig^ i_ 20. 3 Voigt, I. N. IV. 517. Digitized by Microsoft® ACTIO PYBLIOIANA. 141 N" Negidio vendidit et tradidit Its effect was to protect the bona fide purchaser even of a res mancipi against the legal owner who attempted to set up his dominium ex iure Quiritium. On the other hand the actio Publiciana in its alternative form, was based on two Edicts worded somewhat as follows: (i) SI QVIS ID QVOD EI TRADITVM EST EX IVSTA CAVSA A DOMINO ET NONDVM VSVCAPTVM PETET, IVDICIVM DABO\ (ii) SI QVIS ID QVOD BONA FIDE EMIT ET EI TRADITVM EST NON A DOMINO ET NONDVM VSV- CAPTVM PETET, IVDICIVM DABO I The precise wording of these Edicts is much dis- puted, but the question of their correct emendation is too large to be discussed here. The formula of an actio Publiciana based on the second Edict is given by Gaius '" and ran as follows : Si quern hominem A^ Agerius* emit et qui ei tradittis est anno possedisset, turn si eum hominem de quo agitur eius ex iure Quiri- tium esse oporteret, quanti ea res erit, tantam pecuniam, iudex, N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemnato, s. n.p. a. The usefulness of these actions as a protection to sale is apparent. They secured the buyer in posses- sion of the object sold to him until usucapio had ripened such possession into full dominium ; but they were useful only when his possession had been interrupted and he wished to recover it. On the other hand, the exceptio rei uenditae et traditae pro- 1 Voigt, I. N. IV. 478. 2 Voigt, /. N. IV. 479. 2 IV. 36. ■• BONA FIDE here iDserted by Voigt, I. N. iv. 483, of. 6 Diri. 2. 7. fr. 15. Digitized by Microsoft® 142 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. tected him till the period of tisucapio agaiost the former owner; but it was only usefal where his possession had not been interrupted. The date of the actio Publidana and of this exceptio are not to be fixed with absolute certainty; but it is quite clear that neither of them had anything to do with a Praetor Publicius mentioned by Cicero as having existed about A.v.c. 685'. Though there is no mention of either actio or exceptio in the writers of the Republican period, yet it is clear from some passages of Plautus^ that the tradition of res mancipi sold was in his time a transac- tion protected by the law, and Voigt ^ has shrewdly argued that both actio and exceptio must be older than the actio emti, because the latter aimed at securing delivery (habere licere) which would have been of no use had not delivery already been protected by legal remedies. Now the Fasti Gapitolini report a Consul M. Publicius Malleolus of A. v. c. 5 22*, and the conjecture that he was the author of the actio Publi- dana seems very plausible °. The exceptio rei uen- ditae et traditae was probably somewhat older, for the defensive would naturally precede, not follow, the offensive remedy. Nor can this exceptio in Voigt 's opinion have been contemporary with the actio Publidana, because it does not bear the name of exceptio Publidana, which it otherwise would have borne ° This argument does not seem to me strong, 1 Cie. Cluent. 45. 126. 2 Cure. 4. 2. 8 ; Fers. 4. 3. 64 ; Epid. 3. 2. 23. ' I. N. XV. 469. < = Praetor in a.v.c. 519. " Voigt, I. N. IV. 505. 6 I. N. iv. 468. Digitized by Microsoft® SALE ENFORCED BY EDICT. 143 since we know that the famous exceptio doli was not called exceptio Aquiliana. But the point is not an important one. It is enough to be able to say with approximate certainty that the exceptio rei uenditae et traditae and the actiones Puhlicianae were intro- duced by some Praetor about A.v.c. 520. Still the agreement of sale was not yet enforce- able as such. In private affairs it remained what it had been from the time of the XII Tables, a formless agreement supported only by the mores of the com- munity, whereas in public affairs it was still techni- cally a pactum as before, except that the publicity of sales made by the Quaestors gave to their terms a peculiarly binding force. The solemnity always attaching to transactions done in the presence of the people was, as we have seen, at the root of this respect paid to the public uenditio. At last the Praetor of some year decided to make the emiio uenditio of private law the ground of an action, and thus put it on a level with the public uenditiones. We do not know the terms of the important Edict by which the actio emti was introduced, but the formula of the action (ex uendito) brought by the seller is partly given by Gains ^ and must have been as follows : Quod Aulus Agerius mensam N" Negidio uendidit, quidqvid paret oh earn rem iV™ Negidium A" Agerio dare facere oportere ex fide bona'', eius, index, N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemnato. s. n. p. a. The intentio here was exactly the same as that of the actio ex stipulatu, and was probably its prototype, both of them being equally 1 IV. 131. 2 cio. Off. III. 16. 66. Digitized by Microsoft® 144 CONTRACTS OF THE lYS GENTIVM. bonae fidei actions. The formula of the action (ex emto) brought by the purchaser was worded in like fashion: Quod A' Agerius de N" Negidio hominem quo de agitur emit, quidquid oh earn rem N^ Negidium A" Agerio dare facer e oportet ex fide bona, eiv^, index, t&C. (&C. The age of the a^tio emti has been very hotly disputed, and the most knotty question has been whether the action existed or not in the days of Plautus, who died A.v.c. 570. The chief opponent of the affirmative theory has been Bekker', but the arguments of Demelius", Costa', Voigt* and Bech- mann' are so convincing that little doubt on the subject can any longer be entertained. It appears absolutely certain that the actio emti was a feature of the law as Plautus knew it. An elaborate proof of this proposition has been so well given by Demelius and Costa that it is not necessary to do more than sum up the evidence. (i) The contract of emtio uenditio was discussed by Sex. Aelius Paetus Catus (Cos. A.V.C. 556) pro- bably in his Tripertita, and by C. Liuius Drusus (Cos. A.v.c. 642)«. (ii) The aedilician Edict, which presupposed that emtio uenditio was actionable, is mentioned by Plautus '. (iii) We find in Plautus many passages which are only intelligible on the supposition that emtio ' AU. I. 146, note 38. ^ z.fiir SG. ii. 177. 3 Dir. Pnvato 365-73. * I. N. iv. 542. 5 Kauf, I. pp. 511-526. « 19 Dig. 1. 38. 7 Capt. 4. 2. 43. Digitized by Microsoft® INSTANCES IN PLAUTUS. 145 uenditio was actionable. For instance in Mostel- laria^, where the son of Theuropides pretends to have bought a house, and where the owner of the house is represented as begging for a rescission of the sale, we cannot suppose, as Bekker does''', that fides was the only thing which bound the owner. Had it not been for the existence of the actio emti he could not have been represented as trying to have the sale cancelled'. Again, in Act 5, Scene 1, the slave Tranio ad- vises his master Theuropides to call the owner into court and bring an action for the mancipation of the house *, and this can be nothing else than a reference to the actio ex emto. In the same play° it is also plain that hona fides was a principle controlliiig the iudicium ex emto. Again in Persa ' it is clear that Sagaristio, when selling the slave-girl, would not have taken such pains to disclaim all warranty if he could not have been compelled by the actio emti to make good the loss sustained by the purchaser. To prevent this liability Sagaristio is careful to throw the whole periculum on the buyer. Why should he have done so, had there been no actio emti ? Again in Rudens the leno, who had taken earnest-money for the sale of a slave girl and had then absconded with her, would not have been so much afraid of meeting the buyer Plesidippus, if he 1 3. 1. and 2. ^ de Empt. Vend. p. 16. 3 3. 2. 110. * 5. 1. 43. Cf. Gai. iv. 181. « 3. 1. 139. 8 4. 4. 114. and 4. 7. 5. B. E. 10 Digitized by Microsoft® 146 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS 0ENTIVM. had not feared the actio emti. And when the slave girl was finally abiudicata from the leno *, Demelius and Costa are unquestionably right in regarding this as a result of a iudicivmi ex emto. Bekker's opinion that it was the result of a uindicatio in libertatem seems hardly to agree with the fact that the leno is not represented as knowing of her free status till two scenes later''. We might multiply instances, but the evidence is so fully given by others that it is not worth repeating. The general conclusion to be drawn from the above facts is that emtio uenditio became actionable before A.v.c. 550; and, if our argument be right, later than 520, the date of the actio Publiciana. From Plautus we gather further that arrha or arrhabo, the pledge or earnest money which Gaius mentions in this connection, was often given to bind the bargain of sale as well as other bargains. From this it has been argued that pure consensus must have been insufficient to make the contract binding'; but, if that be so, why should the arrha have been used in Gains' day, when we know that sale was purely consensual ? In Rudens " it is clear that the arrhabo was not a necessary part of the transaction, but a mere piece of evidence, so that arrhahonem acceperat simply means uendiderat^. The use of arrhaho is mentioned also in Mostellaria^ and Poenulus^. It was probably forfeited by the purchaser in case the bargain fell through. ^ 5. 1. 1. 2 5. 3—8. ' Bekker, Heid. Krit. Jahrschrift, i. 444. ■* 2. 6. 70. « Brid. Prol. 45-6. 6 3. 1. 111—4. 4. 21. ' 5. 6. 22. Digitized by Microsoft® WARRANTY IN SALE. 147 Having now seen how the actio emti uenditi originated and what was its probable age, let us see what obligations were imposed by the conclusion of the sale upon each of the parties to it : (1) Upon the purchaser (emtor). His chief duty was reddere pretium, to pay the price agreed upon', and if the price consisted partly of things in kind, his duty was to deliver them " ; but according to Voigt ' there was no obli- gation iipon him to do more than deliver. A duty which the purchaser seems very early to have acquired was that of compensating the seller for mora on his part *. (2) Upon the vendor (tienditor-). His chief duty was rem praestare ° (or rem habere licere), to give quiet possession to the vendee ; but this did not include the obligation to convey dominium ex iure Quiritium,". The actio emti, as we have now examined it, enforced three things : (1) recognition of the con- sensual agreement of sale, (2) delivery by the seller, (3) prompt payment by the buyer. Thus it dealt with three of the elements involved in the general conception of sale. The fourth element, that of warranty, remains to be considered. We know that this fourth element was covered by the actio emti in the time of Ulpian, but it does not seem to have been so during the Eepublic. Both Muirhead' and Bechmann* have involved the ' Varro, R. R. n. 2. 6. ^ Cato, R. R. 150. 3 /. N. in. 985. ^ 19 Dig. 1. 38 fr. 1. « 19 Dig. 1. 11. " 19 Dig. 1. 30 ; 18 Dig. 1. 25. !■ R. Law, p. 285.. ^ Kauf. i. 505. 10—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 148 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. subject in unnecessary difficulty by confusing a honae fidei contract of sale with one in which warranty was employed. They speak as though bona fides included warranty, a proposition not necessarily tnie and of which we have no proof. It appears, on the contrary, that the actio emti to enforce warranty was of much later origin than the actio emti to enforce consensual sale '. We have therefore to inquire how warranty was originally given and how it was made good. The only kind of warranty which we have hitherto encountered is that against eviction implied in every mancipatio and enforced by the actio auctoritatis. This method was but of limited scope, since it ap- plied only to res mancipi. After the introduction of the condictio incerti, it became possible to embody warranties in the form of a stipulation. This was accomplished in one or more of the following ways : (1) The stipulatio duplae specified the warranty given by the vendor, and provided in case of a breach for liquidated damages in the shape of a poena dupli, which was doubtless copied from the duplwm of the a^tio auctoritatis. The best specimens of this stipu- lation are texts 1 and 2 of the Transylvanian Tablets printed by Bruns ''-. It was apparently used in those sales of res mancipi, which were consummated not by mancipatio but by traditio '. Its superiority to the warranty afforded by the actio auctoritatis was that it guaranteed quality as well as title, which the actio 1 Girard, Slip, de Garantte, N. R. H. de D. vii. p. 545 note. ^ Font. p. 256. ^ Varro, B. R. ii. 10. 5. Digitized by Microsoft® STIPULATIONS OF WARRANTY. 149 auctoritatis could not do. The Tablets indeed show that the warranties against defects in this stipulation "were exceedingly comprehensive, and that it defended against eviction not only the buyer, but also those in privity with him (emtorem eumue ad quern ea res per- tinebit). (2) We also find a stipulatio simplae, of which the best instances are texts 3 and 4 of the Transyl- vanian Tablets and which, according to Varro ^ might be used as an alternative to the stipulatio duplae, if preferred by the two parties. Its aim in securing the buyer against eviction and defects was precisely the same as that of the former stipulation; its only difference being that the damages were but half the former amount, i.e. were exactly measured by the price of the thing sold. Girard and Voigt are probably wrong in identifying this stipulation used for res mancipi with the next one, which was apparently used only in sales of res nee man- cipi. (3) Another stipulation of frequent occurrence was the stipulation recte habere licere. This guaran- teed quiet possession so far as the seller was con- cerned. Its scope was therefore not so wide as that of the stipulatio siviplae or duplae. The vendor simply promised recte habere licere, but specified no penalty in the event of his non-performance, so that the action on the stipulation must have been a condictio incerti, in which the damages were assessed by the judge. The import of the word 'recte' was doubtless not the same as that of ex fide bona ; but, 1 R. R. II. 2. 5. Digitized by Microsoft® 150 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. as Bechmann ^ has pointed out, it simply implied a waiver of technical objections. (4) A stipulation as to quality alone is men- tioned by Varro " as annexed to the sale of oxen and other res mancipi. The vendor simply promised sanos praestari, so that in this case also the remedy was condictio incerti for judicial damages. (5) A satisdatio secundum mancipiimi is also mentioned by Cicero' and in the Baetic Tablet ^ But its nature and form are quite uncertain. Its name implies that it had some connection with auctoritas, and the most likely theory seems to be that it was a stipulation of suretyship, by which security was given for the auctor, either to insure his appearance (and if so, it was a form of uadimo- nium/') or to guarantee his payment of the poena dupli, in the event of eviction (and if so, it was a form oifideiiissio '). The three first of the above stipulations prove that even in the early Empire (a.d. 160 is the sup- posed date of the Transylvanian Tablets) actio emii was not yet an action for implied warranty. Ulpian's language also indicates that the implication of war- ranty was a new doctrine in his day '. Thus far we have seen that stipulations of war- ranty were customary, and that by the stipulatio duplae or simplae both title and quality were secured. The next step was to make these stipu- 1 Kauf. I. p. 639. ^ ii. 5. 11. » ad Att. V. 1. 2. * Bruns, Fcmtes, p. 251. " Varro, vi. 7. 54. ^ gge Girard, loc. cit. p. 551. ' 21 Dig. 1. 31 fr. 20. Digitized by Microsoft® LOGATIO OONDVGTIO. 151 lations compulsory, and this was first accomplished by the Aediles, in their Edict regulating, among other things, sales in the open market. Plautus mentions this Edict, and refers to the rule of red- hibitio which it enforced \ The first positive mention of aedilician regulations as to warranty occurs how- ever in Cicero ^ and from this it appears that the Aediles first compelled a stipulatio duplae in the sale of slaves. This innovation was doubtless intended to punish slave dealers, who were, as Plautus shows, a low and dishonest class, by imposing upon them the old penalty of duplum. The two aedilician actions which could be brought, if the stipulatio duplae had not been given, were (1) the actio redhibitoria, avail- able within two months, and by which the vendor had to restore the duplum of the price"; (2) the actio quanti emtoris intersit*, available within six months for simple damages. Further than this, however, the law of the Republic did not advance. It was not till the day of Trajan and Septimius Severus that the stipulations of warranty were compulsory for other things than slaves*, and we cannot therefore here trace the development of warranty to its consummation. Art. 2. LocATio Condvctio. The word locare has no technical equivalent in English, for it some- times expresses the fact of hiring, sometimes that of being hired. It means literally to place, to put out. 1 Capt. i. 2. 44 ; Bud. 2. 3. 42 ; Most. 3. 2. 113. 2 Off. III. 17. 71. 3 21 Dig. 1. 45. « 21 Dig. 1. 28. 5 Girard, N. B. H. de D. viii. p. 425. Digitized by Microsoft® 152 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GBNTIVM. As we say that a capitalist places his money, so the Romans said of him pecunias locat\ The State was said opios locare when it paid a contractor for doiag a job, while the gladiator who got paid for fight- ing was said operas locare. This contract was con- sensual and bi-lateral like emtio uenditio, and had a very similar origin. It is easy indeed to see that for a long time there was no distinction made between locatio and uenditio. The latter meant originally, as we have seen, to transfer for a consideration, and thus included the hire as well as the sale of an object. Festus accordingly says that the locationes made by the Censors were originally called uendi- tiones ^ The confusion thus produced left its traces deeply imprinted in the later law, for we find Gaius' remarks on locatio condiictio chiefly devoted to a discussion of how in certain doubtful cases the line should be drawn between that and emtio uen- ditio. Like emtio uenditio, this contract was developed in connection with the administration of public busi- ness. The public affairs in which contractual relations necessarily arose were of four kinds ' : (1) Sales of public property, such as land, slaves, etc., which devolved upon the Quaestors. This class of transactions produced the contract of emtio uen- ditio, as above explained. (2) Contracts for the hire of public servants, generally known as apparitores. These were the lictores and other attendants upon the different ' Most. 1. 3. 85. ^ Festus, s. u. uenditiones. " Mommsen, Z. der Sav. Stif. R. A: vi. 262. Digitized by Microsoft® VARIOUS FORMS OF HIRE. 153 magistrates, and were naturally engaged by those whom they respectively served. This hiring gave rise to the contract known as condiictio operarum, while the offer of such services to the State con- stituted locatio operarum. (3) Business agreements connected with public work, such as the building of temples or bridges, the collection of revenue, etc. This class was in charge of the Censors \ and developed the contract of locatio operis, while the transaction viewed from the standpoint of the contractor became known as conductio operis. (4) Agreements for the supply of various kinds of necessaries for the service of the State, such as beasts of burden, waggons, provisions, etc. This hiring produced the contract known as conductio rei, while the contractors who supplied such commodities were said rem locare. Thus the first group of public transactions gave birth to the contract of sale in private law, while the three last groups each became the parent of one of the three forms of the contract of hire. Just as uenditio seems to have been the original equivalent of locatio, so must emtio have been the original term for what was afterwards known as conductio. Conducere can originally have applied only to the second class of agreements; it must have denoted the collecting and bringing together of a body of apparitores. Afterwards, when the notion of hiring became conspicuous, conducere doubt- less lost its narrow meaning, and was extended to 1 Liu. xMi. 3. Digitized by Microsoft® 154 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. the pther two kinds of hire, as the correlative to locare '- The wholly distinct origin of these various kinds of locatio conductio, and the fact that they were transacted by different magistrates, are sufficient reasons for the curious distinction which the classical jurisprudence always drew between locatio conductio r&i, operis and operarum. A trace of the old word emere as equivalent to conducere always remained in the word redemtor, meaning a contractor for public works. This term was never applied to the apparitor, since it was he who took the initiative and who was thence regarded as a locator operarwm. When the conception of locatio conductio became separated from that of emtio uenditio it is impossible to determine. But since the two transactions appear in Plautus distinct as well as enforceable, and since the contract of sale was only recognised shortly before Plautus' day, the conceptions of sale and of hire pro- bably became quite distinct before either transaction became actionable. We can trace in many passages of Plautus the three forms locatio rei", locatio operis', locatio operarum* ; and it can hardly be imagined that these contracts could have been so common and so distinctly marked had they not been provided with actions. Voigt ' however is of opinion that the three different forms of locatio conductio became actionable at different periods. Locatio conductio ' Mommsen, ib. p. 266. 2 Pseud. 4. 7. 90 ; Merc. 3. 2. 17. 3 Bacch. i. 3. 115 ; Persa, 1. 3. 80. * Aul. 2. 4. 1 ; Merc. 3. 4. 78 ; Epid. 2. 3. 8. = I. N. IV. 596, ff. Digitized by Microsoft® AGE OF THE VARIOUS FORMS. 155 operis and operarwm he places earliest, and admits that they were known as contracts by the middle of the sixth century, which would bring them very nearly to the age of emtio uenditio ; but from Cato ^ he infers that locatio conductio rei was of later origin and that it did not become actionable until the first half of the seventh century. The earliest actual mention that we possess of locatio conductio is by Quintus Mucins Scaeuola, author of 18 books on the IxiS Giuile'', whom Cicero quotes^, though we cannot tell whether the quotation refers to all kinds of locatio conductio or only to the locatio conductio operis. Certain it is that in Cato ' locatio conductio rei seems to be treated rather as emtio uenditio fructus rei. It is also remarkable that lo- catio conductio rei is seldom mentioned in Plautus ^ and so briefly that we can form no conclusion as to whether it was or was not actionable; whereas on the contrary locatio conductio operis and operarum appear very often and exhibit all the marks of ' thoroughly developed contracts. For instance, the locatio conductio operancni in Asinaria" contains a lex commissoria, and that in Bacchides'' provides for a bond to be given by the locator operarum binding him to release the person whose operae he had been employing, as soon as the work was finished. Again in Miles Gloriosus^ the technical term improbare opus is used to express the rejection of work badly carried out by a contractor. All this points to the 1 R. B. 149. 2 i.y.c. 661-672. •* Off. in. 17. 70. * R. R. 149, 150. 5 Cure. 4. 1. 3 ; Merc. 3. 2. 17. 6 1. 8. 76. ' 1. 1. 8. ? 4. 4. 37. Digitized by Microsoft® 156 CONTRACTS OF THE IV8 GENTIVM. existence of an action for locatio conductio operarum and for locatio conductio operis at the time when Plautus wrote'; hut Voigt seems right in concluding that locatio conductio rei did not become actionable till a good deal later. The origin of this action, as of the actio emti, was in the Praetor's Edicts and in form it differed but little from the actio emti uenditi. Like the latter it was bonae fidei^ and its form {ex locato) must have been as follows : Quod A^ Agerius N" Negidio operas locauit, quidquid paret oh earn rem N™ Negi- dium A" Agerio dare facere oportere ex fide bona, eius, iudex, N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemnato. s. n. p. a. Like emtio uenditio it is also clear that locatio conductio of all kinds could be made by mere consensus, and that from the first it must have been a 6onae fidei contract like its prototjrpe. The writings of Oato * are our chief authority for the existence of the locatio conductio operis and operarum in the second half of the seventh century, and for the manner in which these locationes were contracted. It appears to have been customary to draw up with care the terms (leges locationis) of such contracts, and when these were committed to writing, as they doubtless must have been, they exactly corresponded to the contracts made in modem times between employers and contractors. Already in the Kepublican period the jurists had ^ So Demelins, Z.filr RG. ii. 193 ; Bechmann, Kauf. i. p. 526 j but Bekker denies it Z.fUr RG. iii. 442. ■•i .50 Dig. 16. 5. ^ Cic. N. D. iii. 30. 74 ; Off. a. 18. 64. * R. R. 141-5. Digitized by Microsoft® FURTHER DISTINCTIONS. 157 begun to subdivide the classes of contracts above mentioned. (1) They distinguished between various sorts of locatio cmiductio rei. There was (a) rei locatio frii- endae in which the use of the object was granted ^ (6) rei locatio ut eadem reddatur in which the object itself had to be returned, and (c) rei locatio ut eiusdein generis reddatur ''■ in which a thing of the same kind might be returned. (2) The two kinds of locatio condiictio operis were also most probably distinguished at an early date into : (a) locatio rei faciendae in which a thing was given out to be made (epyov), and (6) locatio operis faciendi^ in which a job was given out to be done {aTTOTeXea/jia). (3) Locatio condvxtio operarum alone does not seem to have been subdivided in any way. The object of these distinctions was doubtless to define in each case the rights and duties of the conductor. The technical expression for the remu- neration in locatio conductio was m,erx*, and it was always a sum of money, probably because it was originally paid out of the aerarium and therefore could not conveniently have been given in kind. The fact that in Plautus the word pretium was often used instead of merx, shows that the distinction between locatio conductio and emtio uenditio was still of recent origin when he wrote; but our general conclusion must be that this contract was known ^ Gai. III. 145 ; Lex agraria, c. 25. 2 19 Dig. 2. 31 ; 34 Dig. 2. 34. 3 19 Dig. 2. 30 ; 50 Dig. 16. 5. * Varro, L. L. v. 36. Digitized by Microsoft® 158 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. to him in some at least of its forms, and that in all its branches it arrived at full maturity in the Republican period. It is worth remembering that the Lex Rhodia de iactu, the parent of the modern law of general average, was enforced by means of this action. The owner sued the ship's magister ex locato, and the magister forced other owners to contribute by suing them ex conducto\ This law was discussed in Re- publican times by Servius Sulpicius and Ofilius". Art. 3. Before proceeding further with our history of the ius gentmm contracts we must notice the important innovation made by the Edict Pacta conuenta, the author of which was C. Cassius Longi- nus, Praetor A.v.c. 627'. We have seen how the pactum uenditionis and the pactwn locationis had been recognised and transformed into regular con- tracts about seventy years before this time. The present Edict gave legal recognition to pacta in general, and thus rendered immense assistance in the development of formless Contract. Its language was somewhat as follows^: PACTA CONVENTA, QVAE NEC VI NEC DOLO MALO NEC AD- VEESVS LEGES PLEBISCITA EDICTA MAGISTKATVVM FACTA ERVNT, SERVABO. The scope of the Edict was, however, less broad than might at iirst be supposed. It might well be understood to mean that all lawful agreements would thenceforth be judicially enforceable. But as a matter of fact the test of what should constitute » Camazza, Bir. Com. p. 172. ■' 14 Dig. 2. 2. fr. 3. 3 Voigt, Bom. EG. i. 591. ■• 2 Big. 14. 7. fr. 7. Digitized by Microsoft® EDICT PACTA OONVENTA. 159 an enforceable pactum lay in the discretion of the individual Praetor. He might or might not grant an action, according as the particular agree- ment set up by the plaintiff did or did not appear to him a valid one. This Edict was therefore nothing more than an official announcement that the Praetor would, in proper cases, give effect to pacta which had never before been the objects of judicial cognizance. It needs no explanation to show what important results such an Edict was sure to produce, even in the hands of the most conservative Praetors; and accordingly we find that in the next century new varieties of formless contract arose from the habitual enforcement by the Praetor of corresponding pacta. The mode in which tentative recognition was accorded to the new praetorian pacta was the devising of an actio in factum^ to suit each new set of circumstances. The formula of such an action simply set forth the agreement, and directed the judge to assess damages if he should find it to have been broken. This was doubtless the means by which societas, mandatum, depositivm, commoda- tum, pignus, hypotheca, receptum, constitutum — in short, all the contractual relations originating in the last century of the Kepublic — were at first protected and enforced. A curious historical parallel might be drawn between these actiones in factum and our "actions on the case." Not only are the terms almost synonymous, but the adaptability of each class of actions to new circumstances was equally remarkable; and the part played by the 1 2 Dig. 14. 7. fr. 2. Digitized by Microsoft® 160 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. latter class in the expansion of the English Law of Tort bears a striking reseniblance to that played by the former in the development of the Roman Law of Contract. We shall see specimens of the actio in factum based upon the edict Pacta conuenta, when we come to examine the various contracts of the later Re- public which all owed their origin to the Praetor's Edict. Art. 4. Mandatvm. The age of the actio man- dati is difficult to fix, but there are good reasons for believing that it was the third bonae fidei action devised by the Praetor, and that it is older than the actio pro socio. Mandatv/m was an agreement whereby one person, at the request of another, usually his friend', undertook the gratuitous per- formance of something to the iaterest of that others In short, it was a special agency in which the agent received no remuneration. Its gratuitous character was essential, for where the agent was paid, the transaction was regarded as a case of locatio conductio. We know that the testamentum per aes et libram was virtually a mandatum to the familiae emtor', and that fideicommissa, which began to be important towards the end of the Republic, were nothing but mandata*; it is plain too that as an informal trans- action mandatum, must always have been practised long before it became recognised by the Praetor. The earliest piece of direct evidence^ which we 1 Cie. Eosc. Am. 39. 112. == Gai. iii. 156. s Gai. II. 102. 4 Ulp. Frag. 25. 1-3. » Auot. ad Her. ii. 13. 19. Digitized by Microsoft® MAJVDATVAf. 161 have as to the actio mandati is that it existed in A.V.C. 631 under the Praetorship of S. lulius Caesar. It is probable that the action was then of recent origin, and represented the first-fruits of the Edict Pacta conuenta^, for Caesar treated it as non- hereditary, whereas the Praetor Marcus Drusus soon afterwards granted an actio in h&redem according to the rule of the later law'' From Plautus it distinctly appears that Tnandatum was a well developed institution in his day, but there is no evidence to prove that an actio mandati already existed. The transaction is often mentioned', and must have been necessary in the active commercial life which Plautus has pourtrayed. In Trinummus*, for instance, we see a regular case of mandatv/m generate. The phrase "mandare fidei et fiduciae" here indicates that fides pure and simple was the only support on which mandatum rested, and that there was no motive beyond friendly feeling to compel the performance of the mandatum. On the other hand the word infamia is thought to have had a technical meaning, as an allusion to the fact that the actio mxvndati was fam,osa ^ ; but this is surely a flimsy basis for Demelius' opinion that the actio mandati was in existence as early as the middle of the sixth century *. It seems much safer to regard this action as 1 Voigt, Rom. EG. i. 681. ^ 17 Dig. 1. 53. ' E.g. Bacch. 3. 3. 71-5 ; Gapt. 2. 2. 93 ; Asin. 1. 1. 107 ; Epid. 1. 2. 27, 31 ; Gist. i. 2. 53. ■< 1. 2. 72-121. 5 Cic. pi-o S. Rose. 38. Ill ; Gaec. 3. 7. « Z. fur EG. II. 198 ; Costa, Dir. Priv. p. 390. B. E. 11 Digitized by Microsoft® 162 CONTBACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. younger than those of emtio iienditio and locatio conductio, and to trace its origin to the influence of the Edict Pacta conuenta. The earliest form of relief granted to the agent against his mandator was doubtless an actio in factwrn,, based upon that Edict, and having a formula of this kind^ : Si paret N™ Negidium A" Agerio, cv/ni is in potestate l!- Titii esset, mandauisse ut pro se solioeret, et A™ Agerium emancipatum soluisse, quanti ea res erit, tantam pecuniam index N^ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. When at length the Praetor was prepared to- recognise mandatum as a regular contract of the ius duile, he placed it on an equal footing with the older bonae fidei contracts by granting the actio mandati, with its far more flexible formula in ius concepta. The actio mandati directa brought by the principal against the agent had the following formula : Quod A' Agerius N" Negidio rem curandam man- dauit, quidquid paret oh earn rem N™ Negidium A" Agerio darefacerepraestare oportere ex fide bona, eius, iudex, N"^ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. In the actio contraria, by which the agent sued the principal, the formula began as above, but the condemnatio was different, thus: quidquid paret ob eam rem A™ Agerium N" Negidio dare facere praestare oportere e. f. b. eius A™ Agerium N" Negidio condemna. s. n. p. a. Or again, where the claims and counter-claims were conflicting, the condemnatio might be made still more indefinite, thus : 1 17 Dig. 1. 12. fr. 6. Digitized by Microsoft® GROWTH OF ACTIO MANDATI. 163 quidquid paret oh earn rem alterum alteri dare facere praestare oportere e. f. b. eius alterum alteri condemna. s. n. p. a.' Unfortunately we do not know the language of the Edict by which the actio mandati was instituted; but the fact that it was modelled on the actions of sale and hire is one that nobody disputes. There is no direct authority for assuming the existence of an actio in factum in this case, as there is in the cases of commodatum and depositum, where we have Gaius' express statement to that effects But it is clear, from Gaius' allusion to "quaedam causae" and from his use of "uelut," that double formulae existed in many other actions. We may well accept Lenel's ingenious theory' that the exist- ence of an actio contraria always indicates the existence of formulae in ius and in factum conceptae, and the assumption here made is therefore no rash conjecture. The conception of mandatum changed somewhat before the end of the Republic. It meant at first any charge general or special*. But by Cicero's time it had acquired the narrow meaning, which it retained throughout the classical period, of a par- ticular trust ^, while procuratio was used of a general trust °, and its remedy was the actio negotiorum ges- torum ' Thus it still remains for us to inquire to what 1 Lenel, Ed. Perp. p. 235. 2 Gai. IV. 47. ' Ed. Perp. p. 202. * Cato, R. R. 141-3. = 17 Dig. 1. 48. 6 Cic. Top. 10. 42. ' Gai. in 3 Dig. 3. 46. 11—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 164 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. extent procuratio, i.e. general agency, was practised, as distinguished from mandatv/m generate, i.e. special agency with general instructions, and how general agents (procuratores) were appointed. Now it is one of the most striking features of the Boman Law that agency of this sort was unknown until almost the end of the Republic. How and why so great a commercial people as the Romans managed to do without agency, is a question that has received many different answers. We may be sure that mandatum was practised long before it ever became actionable, but if so, it was practised informally and had no legal recognition. The cir- cumstance which made it almost impossible for general agency to exist was that the Romans held fast to the rigid rule : " id quod nostrum est sine facto nostra ad ahum transferri nan potest \" Such a rule evidently had its origin in the early period when contracts were strictly formal, and when he alone who uttered the solemn words or who touched the scales was capable of acquiring rights. In a formal period the rule was natural enough; but the curious thing is that it should not have been relaxed as soon as the real and consensual contracts became important. This fact has sometimes been accounted for on ethical grounds. It has been said that the keen legal conscience of the Romans made them loth to depart from the letter of the law by admitting that a man who entered into a contract could possibly thereby acquire anjdihing for anybody else. But the true > 50 Dig. 17. 11. Digitized by Microsoft® RARITY OF AGENCY. 165 reason seems rather to have been a practical one ^ — that the existence of an agency of status precluded that of an agency of contract. Thus we know that householders as a rule had sons or slaves who could receive promises by stipulation, though they could not bind their paterfamilias by a disadvantageous contract; and so to a limited extent agency always existed within the Roman family. It is also obvious that, in an age when men seldom went on long journeys, the necessity for an agent or fully em- powered representative cannot have been seriously felt. Plautus shows however that agency was not developed even in his day, when travel had become comparatively common. In Trimimmus and Mostel- laria, for instance, no prudent friend is charged with the affairs of the absent father, and consequently the spendthrift son makes away with his father's goods by lending or selling them as he pleases \ We can however mark the various stages by which the Roman Law approximated more and more closely to the idea of true agency. 1. The oldest class of general agents were the tutor es to whom belonged the management (gestio) of a ward's or woman's affairs, and the curatores of young men and of the insane. 2. The next oldest kind of general agents were the cognitores, persons appointed to conduct a par- ticular piece of litigation ", and not to be confounded with the cognitores of praediatura *. They were ori- 1 Pemice, Labeo, i. 489. " Trin. 1. 2. 129; Most. 1. 1. 74. 3 2 Verr. in. 60. 137 ; Gaee. 14. * Lex. Malae. 63 ; Cio. Har. Resp. 45. Digitized by Microsoft® 166 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. ginally appointed only in cases of age or illness ^ and their general authority was limited to the manage- ment of the given suit. Gaius has shown us how they were able to conduct an action by having their names inserted in the condemnatio ^ Whether they existed or not under the legis actio procedure is uncertain ; but they probably did, since we know that they were at first appointed in a formal manner =- Subsequently the Edict extended their powers to the informally appointed procuratores. The action by which these agents were made responsible to their principals was after Labeo's time the actio mandati*. During the Republic however and before his time the jurists do not seem to have regarded the relation between cognitor and principal as a case of mandatum, but simply gave an action corresponding to each par- ticular case, as for instance an actio depositi if the cognitor failed to restore a depositwn. 3. Procuratores were persons who in Cicero's day" acted as the agents and representatives of persons absent on public business ^ They often appear to have been' the freedmen of their re- spective principals, and their functions were doubt- less modelled on those of the curatores. The connection between curatores and procuratores is seen in the Digest where pupilli and absent in- dividuals are often coupled together', while the ' Auot. ad Her. ii; 20. " Gai. iv. 86. 3 Gai. IV. 83. ■< 17 Dig. 1. 8. fr. 1. = Quint. 19. 60-62 ; -2 Verr. v. 7. 13 ; Lix lui. Mm. 1. « Gaec. 57. • ' Cio. Or. 2. 249. 8 29 Dig. 7. 2. fr. 3 ; 47 Dig. 10. 17. fr. 11 ; 50 Dig. 17. 124. Digitized by Microsoft® PROOVRATIO. 167 definitions of procurator show that his power was confined to occasions on which his principal was absent \ and the word procuratio itself indicates that it was copied from the curatio of furiosi ^ or of prodigi. One passage of Gaius " seems to imply that the procurator was not always carefully distinguished from the negotioruTn gestor or voluntary agent, and Pernice interprets some remarks of Cicero * as indi- cating the same fact. From this he infers with much likelihood^ that the remedy against the procurator was originally not the actio mandati but the actio negotiorum gestorum^. Even in Labeo's time the actio mandati was probably not well established in the case of procuratores, though it was so by the time of Gains'. A procurator might conduct litigation for the absent principal; but the acquisition of property through an agent was not clearly established even in Cicero's time °, though the principal could always bring an action for the profits of a contract made in his name". 4. Negotiorum gestio was a relation not based upon contract, but consisted m the voluntary in- tervention of a self-appointed agent, who undertook to administer the affairs of some absent or deceased friend. In the Institutes it is classed as a form of 1 Paul. Diac. s.u. cognitor. ' Lex agr. c. 69. 3 IV. 84. ^ Top. 42 and 66. " 17 Dig. 1. 6. fr. 1. •> Labeo, I. 494. ' 4 Dig. 4. 25. fr. 1. 8 3 Dig. 3. 33. " Cic. Att. vi. 1. 4. i» 3 Dig. 3. 46. fr. 4. Digitized by Microsoft® 168 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM, quasi-contract, and it was always regarded as a relation closely analogous to mandatum^. The mode of enforcing claims made by the negotiorum gestor and his principal against one another was the actio negotiormn gestorum, which might, like the actio mandati, be either directa or contraria. It was based upon an Edict worded thus : SI QVIS NEGOTIA ALTERIVS, SIVE QVIS NEGOTIA QVAE CVIVSQVE CVM IS MORITVR FVERINT, GES- SERIT, IVDICIVM EO NOMINE DABOl We do not know the date of this Edict, but it was certainly issued before the end of the Republic, inasmuch as the action founded upon it was discussed by Trebatius and Ofilius'. This action had a formula in ills concepta which ran somewhat as follows : Quod N' Negidius negotia A^ Agerii gessit, qua de re agitur, quidquid oh earn rem N'^ Negidium A" Agerio dare facere praestare oportet ex fide bona, tantam pecuniam index JV'" Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a.* 5. Another means by which agency could prac- tically be brought about was adstipulatio, as we saw above ". This was not a case of true agency, for the adstipulator acquired the claim in his own name, and if he sued upon it, he did so of course in his own right : yet he was treated as agent for the other stipulator and made liable to the actio mandati^. 6. Fideiussio was probably treated as a form of special agency almost from the time of its invention, 1 3 Dig. 5. 18. fr. 2. 2 3 Big. 5. 3. » 17 Big. 1. 22. fr. 10. * Lenel, Ed. Perp. p. 86. ° p. 110. » Gai. III. 111. Digitized by Microsoft® SOOIETAS. 169 since we know that it possessed the remedy of the actio mandati as early as the time of Quintus Mucius Scaeuola ^ Art. 5. SociETAS. This was the common name given to several kinds of contract by which two or more persons might combine together for a common profitq,ble purpose to which they contributed the necessary means. These contracts could be formed by mere consent of the parties, and except in the case of societas uectigalis they were dissolved by the death of any one member, so that even societas in perpetuum meant only an association for so long as the parties should live '. Ulpian distinguishes four kinds of societas": (1) omnium honorum, (2) negotiationis alicuius, (3) rei unius, and (4) uectigalis. The first of these has no counterpart in our modem law, but may be described as a contractual tenancy in common. The second and third may be treated under one head, as societates quaestuariae, corresponding to modem contracts of partnership. The fourth may best be regarded as the Roman equivalent of the modem corporation. Except in the case of this fourth form, which was in most respects unique, the remedy of a socius who had been defrauded, or who considered that the agreement of partnership had been violated, or who wished for an account or a dissolution, was either an actio in factum or the more comprehensive actio pro socio ■*. 1 17 Dig. 1. 48. " 17 Big. 2. 1. 3 17 Dig. 2. 5. * Cic. Rose. Com. 9. Digitized by Microsoft® 170 CONTRACTS OV THE IVS GENTIVM. Both these actions were of praetorian origin, and the former was doubtless the experimental mode of relief which prepared the way for the introduction of the latter. At first we may fairly suppose the Praetor to have granted an actio in factwm adapted to the particular case, with a formula worded some- what as follows : 8i paret iV™ N™ cum A" A° pactum bonuentum^ fecisse de societate ad rem certam emendam ideoque renuntiauisse societati ut solus em^ret^, quanti ea res est tantam pecuniam, iudex, N'^ iV™ A" A" condemna. s. n. p. a. When the pactum societatis had thus been protected, and the juristic mind had grown accustomed to regard societas in the light of a contract, the Praetor then doubtless announced in his Edict that he would grant an actio pro socio to any aggrieved member of a societas. In this way agreements of partnership became fully recognised as contracts, and were provided with an actio in iiis conoepta, the formula of which must have been thus expressed': Quod A' Agerius cum N" Negidio sodetatem coiit universoru/m quae ex quaestu veniunt, quidquid oh eam rem N"^ Negidium A" Agerio (or alterum alteri) pro socio dare facere praestare oportet ex fide bona, eius iudex N™ Negidium A" Agerio (or alterum alteri) condemna. s. n. p. a. The superiority of this honae fidei action to the former remedy, as a mode of adjusting com- plicated disputes arising out of a partnership, is too obvious to require explanation. The actio in 1 17 Dig. 2. 71. "^ 17 Big. 2, 65. ir. 4. 3 Lenel, Ed. Perp. p. 237. Digitized by Microsoft® AGE OF ACTIO PRO SOCIO. l7l factum may still however have proved useful in certain cases. Societas appears in Plautus with much less dis- tinctness than either of the other three consensual contracts. Socius is not used by him in a technical or commercial sense, but means only companion ^ or co-owner^. The nearest approach to an allusion to societas in its more recent form is to be found in Rudens^ where the shares of socii are mentioned; but this is no reason for supposing that Plautus knew of societal as a contract. The date of the actio pro socio is impossible to fix, though Voigt^ has suggested that the Praetor P. Kutilius Rufas must have been its author in the year 646 ^ Abso- lute certainty on the subject is unattainable, because we cannot tell whether this Rutilius originated or merely mentioned the edict, nor can we positively identify him with the Praetor of a.v.c. 646. On these points there is hopeless controversy", so that they must remain unsettled. But what we can do with a certain measure of accuracy, is to trace the process by which societal came to be regarded as a contractual relation, and slowly grew in importance till it called for the creation by the Praetor of a honae fidei action to protect it. This action certainly existed about the end of the seventh century, for it is mentioned in the Lex Julia Municipalis of 1 Bacch. 5. 1. 19 ; Cist. 4. 2. 78. ' Bud. i. 3. 95. ' 1. 4. 20 and 2. 6. 67. * lus N. IV. 603 note 204. 5 38 Dig. 2. 1. " See Husehke, Z. fur Civ. wnd Proc. 14. 19 ; Schilling, Inst. §313. Digitized by Microsoft® 172 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. A.V.C. 709 ^ and was discussed by Quintus Mucius Scaeuola". A closer approximation to the date of its "origin seems to be impossible. 1. Societas omnium bonorum. The original conception of societas seems not to have been that of a commercial combination, but of a family. Not indeed that the term societas was ever applied to the association of father, mother, children and cognates; but they were practically regarded as a single body, each member of which was bound by solemn ties to share the good or bad fortune which befell the rest. The duty of avenging the death of a blood-relation, the duty of providing a certain portion for children, as enforced by the querela inofficiosi testamenti, the obsequia which children owed to their parents, are illustrations of the principle. Now this body, the family, could hold common property: and here is the point at which the family touches the institution of partner- ship. The technical term which expressed the tenancy in common of brothers in the family pro- perty (hereditas), was consortivmi^, and the brother co-tenants were called consortes. This institution of consortium was of great antiquity, being even found in the Sutras*. It is compared by Gellius' to the relation of societas, and arose from the descent or devise of the patrimonial estate to several children who held it undivided. Division might at any time be made among them by the actio familiae 1 Bruns, Font. p. 107. ^ gaj. ni. 149 ; Cic. Off. in. 17. 70. » Cie. 2 Veir. ii. 3. 23 ; Paul. Diao. 72. " Leist, Alt.-Ar. lus Gent. p. 414. ■> i. 9. 12. Digitized by Microsoft® SOCIETAS OMNIVM BONORVM. 173 erciscundas \ but they might often prefer to continue the consortium, either because the property was small, or because they wished to carry on an es- tablished family business. If the latter course was adopted, the tenancy in common became a partner- ship, embracing in its assets the whole wealth of the partners ; and it is easy to see how this natural part- nership, if found to be advantageous, would soon be copied by voluntary associations of strangers. Thus socius, as we know from Cicero*, was often used as a synonym of censors, and there can be no doubt that consortium was the original pattern of the societas omnium bonorum". That there were some differences between the rules of consortium and those of societas does not affect the question. For in- stance *, the gains of the consortes were not brought into the common stock, but those ot socii were; while the death of a socius dissolved the societas, but that of a consors did not ^ dissolve the consortium. These points of difference and others " probably arose from the juristic interpretation applied to societas, when it had once become fairly recognised as a purely commercial contract. But consortium and societas omnium bonorum have two points in common which show that they must have been historically connected, (i) In societas omnium, bonorum there was a complete and immediate transfer of property from the indi- viduals to the societas'', whereas the obligations of ■■ Paul. Diao. s. u. erctum. ^ Brut. i. 2. 3 Leist, Soc. 24 ; Pernioe, Z. der S. Stift. R. A. in. 85. i 17 Dig, 2. 52. * Pernice, Labeo i. p. 69. « See Pernice, Laieo i. 85-6. ' 17 Dig. 2. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 174 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. each remained distinct and were not shared by the others'. Now this is exactly what would have happened in consortium : the property would have been common, but the obligation of each consors would have remained peculiiar to himself, (ii) The treatment of socii as brothers' is clearly also a reminiscence of consortiv/m ; and this conception of fratemitas, being peculiar to the societas omnium bonorum^, makes its connection with the old con- sortium still more evident. The fraternal character of this particular societas is responsible for the existence of a generous rule which subsequently, under the Empire, became extended so as to apply to the other kinds of societas^ The rule was that no defendant in an actio pro socio should be condemned to make good any claim beyond the actual extent of his means ^ This was known as the beneficium competentiae ; and it gave rise to a qualified formula for the actio pro socio, as follows : Quod A' Agerius cum N" Negidio societatem omnium bonorum emit, quidquid 6b earn, rem iV"' Negidium A° Agerio dare f. p. oportet ex f. b. dumtaxat in id quod i\r* Negidius facere potest, quodue dolo malo fecerit quominus possit, eius index N™ Negidiwm A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. 2. Societas negotii uel rei alicuius. This second form of partnership must have been the most common, since it was presumed to be in- tended whenever the term societas was alone used '. 1 17 Dig. 2. 3. 2 17 Dig. 2. 63. ' 17 Dig. 2. 63. * 17 Dig. 2. 63. fr. 1. 42 Dig. 1. 16 and 22. « 17 Dig. 2. 7. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES OF ACTIO PRO SOCIO. 175 It has also been derived from consortium by Lastig\ His theory is that consortes, or brothers, when they undertook a business in partnership with one another^, often modified their relations by agreement. The special agreement, he thinks, then became the conspicuous feature of the partner- ship, and the relations thus established were copied by associations not of consortes but of strangers. The object of the theory is to explain the correal obligation of partners. This correality did not how- ever exist at Rome^, except in the case of banking partnerships, where we are told that it was a peculiar rule made by custom*, so that Lastig's theory lacks point. A further objection^ is that this theory does not explain, but is absolutely inconsistent with, the exist- ence of the actio pro socio as an actio famosa. The fraternal relations existing between consortes could never have suggested such a remedy, for Cicero in his defence of Quinctius lays great stress on the enormity of the brother's conduct in having brought such a humiliatiag action against his client. Another explanation of the actio pro socio is given by Leist". He derives it from the actio so- cietatis given by the Praetor against freedmen who refused to share their earnings with their patrons. This societas of the patron must have been a one- sided privilege, like his right to the freedman's 1 Z. filr ges. Handelsrecht. xxiv. 409-428. 2 As in 26 Dig. 7. 47. 6. 3 14 Dig. 3. 13. 2 ; 17 Dig. 2. 82. * Auet. ad Her. ii. 13. 19 ; 2 Dig. 14. 9, 5 As Perniee has pointed out, Labeo i. p. 94. 6 Soc. p. 32. Digitized by Microsoft® 176 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. services' ; for the freedman could never have brought an action against his patron, since he was not entitled to any share in the patron's property. The actio societatis was therefore a penal remedy available only to the patron, and consequently it cannot pos- sibly have suggested the bilateral actio pro socio of partners. Nor can the bonae fidei character of the actio pro socio be explained if we assume such an origin. The most reasonable view appears to be that which regards the actio pro socio as the outcome of necessity. The Praetor saw partnerships springing up about him in the busy life of Rome. He saw that the mutual relations of socii were unregulated by law, as those of adpromissores had been before the legislation described above in Chapter v. He found that an actio in factum, based on the Edict Pax>ta conuenta, was but an imperfect remedy; and as an addition to the Edict was then the simplest method of correcting the law, it was most natural for him to institute an actio pro socio, in which bona fides was made one of the chief requisites simply because the mutual relations of socii had hitherto been based upon fides \ 3. Societas uectigalium uel pMicanorwm. This kind of societas was a corporation rather than a partnership, and we have proof in Livy that such corporations existed long before the other kinds of societas came to be recognised as contracts. These 1 38 Dig. 2. 1. 2 Cie. Quint. 6. 26 ; Q. Rose. 6. 16 ; S. Rose. 40. 116 ; 2 Verr. III. 58. 134. Digitized by Microsoft® SOGIETAS AND COLLEGIVM. 177 societates acted as war-contractors^ collectors of taxes ^, and undertakers of public works'. In one passage in Livy * they are called redemtores, and we find three societates during the second Punic War in A.v.c. 539" supplying the State with arms, clothes and com. It was perhaps the success of these societates publica- norwm" which iatroduced the conception of com- mercial and voluntary partnership. But still they were utterly unlike partnerships', so that their his- tory must have been quite different from that of the other societates. They were probably derived from the ancient sodalitates or collegia^, which were per- petual associations, either religious (e.g. augurium collegia), or administrative {quaestorum collegia), or for mutual benefit, like the guilds of the Middle Ages (fabrorwm collegia). This theory of their origia is based upon three points of strong resem- blance which seem to justify us in establishing a close connection between societas and collegium: (1) Both were regulated by law", and were established only by State concessions or charters. (2) Both had a perpetual corporate existence, and were not dissolved by the death of any one member "- (3) Both were probably of Greek origin. We > Liu. XXXIV. 6 in a.v.c. 559. ^ Liu. xxvii. 3 (a.v.c. 544). » Liu. XXIV. 18 (A.V.C. 540) ; Cic. 2 Verr. i. 50. 150. • XLii. 3 (a.v.c. 581). ' Liu. xxiii. 48-9. " Liu. xxxix. 44 ; XXV. 3. '3 Dig. 4. 1. 8 Lex rep. of a.v.c. 631, cap. 10 ; Cic. leg. agr. ii. 8. 21 ; pro domo 20. 51 ; PUnc. 15. 36. 9 GaiuB, 3 Dig. 4. 1 ; 47 Dig. 22. 1. "I 28 Dig. 5. 59 fr. 1 ; 17 Dig. 2. 59 ; Cic. Brut. i. 1. B. E. 12 Digitized by Microsoft® 178 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. are told that societates publiccmorum existed at Athens', while Gaius^ derives from a law of Solon the rule applying to all collegia, that they might make whatever bye-laws they pleased, provided these did not conflict with the public law. These three facts may well lead us to derive this particular form of societas from the collegium. We know further that the jurists looked upon it as quite different from the ordinary societas, and that it did not have the actio pro socio as a remedy'- The president or head of the societas was called manceps*, or magister if he dealt with third parties ', and the modes of suretyship which it used in its corporate transactions were praedes and praedia', another mark perhaps of its semi-public origin. 1 Arist. Bep. Ath. 52. 3 and of. Voigt, I. N. ii. 401. 2 47 Dig. 22. 4. 3 Voigt, Rom. BG. i. 808. * Ps. Asc. in Cio. Diu. ; Paul. Diao. 151 s. u. manceps ; Cio. dam. 10. 25 ; Cic. Plane. 26. 64. ' Paul. Diac. s. u. magisterare ; Cic. Att. v. 5. 3 ; Cio. 2 Verr. 11. 70. 169 ; ib. III. 71. 167. ' Lex Mai. c. 65. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER VII. CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. Part II. Real Contracts. Art. 1. MvTWM. We have not yet really dis- posed of all the consensual contracts, for we now come to a class of obligations entered into without formality and by the mere consent of the parties, but ia which that consent was signified in one par- ticular way, i.e. by the delivery of the object in respect of which the contract was made. The con- tracts of this class have therefore been teirmed Eeal contracts, though they might with equal propriety be called Consensual. The oldest of them all is mutumn, the gratuitous loan of res fungibiles, and it stands apart from the other contracts of its class in such a marked way, that its peculiarities can only be understood from its history. It differed from the other so-called real contracts, (i) ia having for its remedy the condictio, an actio stricti iuris; (ii) in being the only one which conveyed ownership in the objects lent, and did not require them to be returned in specie. Both peculiarities requfre explanation. 12—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 180 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. The most important function of Contract in early- times was the making of money loans, and for this the Romans had three devices peculiarly their own, first Tiexum, then sponsio, and lastly earpensilatio. But these were available only to Roman citizens, so that the legal reforms constituting the so-called ius gentium naturally included new methods of per- forming this particular transaction. One such in- novation was the modification of sponsio, already described, and the rise of stipulatio in its various forms : another was the recognition of an agreement followed by a payment as constituting a valid contract, which might be enforced by the condictio, like the older sponsio and expensilatio. This latter innovation was the contract known as mutuwm. It doubtless originated in custom, and was crystallised in the Edict of some reforming Praetor. As its object was money, or things analogous to money in having no individual importance, such as com, seeds, &c., the object naturally did not have to be returned in, specie by the borrower. Though the bare agreement to repay was suffi- ciently binding as regards the principal sum, the payment of interest on the loan could not be pro- vided for by bare agreement, but had to be clothed in a stipulation. This rule may have been due to the fact that mutuum was originally a loan firom friend to friend ; but it rather seems to indicate that bare consensus was at first somewhat reluctantly tolerated. In Plautus mutuum appears as a gratuitous loan, generally made between friends^ and in sharp con- > Cure. 1. 1. 67 and 2. 3. 51 ; Paeud. 1. 3. 76. Digitized by Microsoft® AGE OF MVTrVM. 181 trast to foenus, a loan with interest', which was always entered into by stipulation. When mutuv/m is used by Plautus to denote a loan on which interest is payable, we must therefore understand that a special agreement to that effect had been entered into by stipulation, since mutuum was essentially gratuitous. From three passages " it is evident that mutuum was recoverable by action in the time of Plautus* (circ. A. V. c. 570), and it seems probable that Livy^ also uses it in a technical sense ^ If then we place the date of the Lex Aebutia as late as A.v.c. 513, and suppose, as Voigt does ', that mutuum being a iuris gentium contract must have been subsequent to that law, we shall be led to conclude that mutuum came into use about the second quarter of the sixth century. This theory as to date is supported by the fact, which Karsten points out', that mutuum would hardly have been possible without a uniform legal tender, and that Rome did not appropriate to herself the exclusive right of coinage till A.v.c. 486. We thus see that the introduction of mutuum and that of emtio uenditio, i.e. of the first real and the first consensual contract, took place at about the same time. As regards its peculiar remedy we know that money lent by mutuum was recoverable by a con- dictio certae pecujiiae, with the usual sponsio and 1 Asin. 1. 3. 95. 2 Trin. 3. 2. 101 ; 4. 3. 44 ; Bacch. 2. 3. 16. 3 Cure. A.v.c. 560. ■^ xxxii. 2. 1. » Of A.v.c. 555. 6 I. N. IV. 614. ' Slip. p. 38. Digitized by Microsoft® 182 CONTRACTS OF THK IVS GENTIVM. restipulatio tertiae partis\ It seems, like expensila- tio, to have received this stringent remedy by means of juristic interpretation, which extended the meaning and the remedy of pecimia certa credita so as to cover this new form of loan. Thus we find credere often used by Plautus in the sense of making a miwtvm/m *. When this final extension had been made iu the meaning of pecunia credita, we may reconstruct the Edict on that subject as follows ° : SI CERTVM PETETVR DE PECVNIA QVAM QVIS CREDIDERIT EXPENSVMVE TVLERIT MVTVOVE DE- DERIT NEVE EX IVSTA CAVSA SOLVERIT PROMISE- RITVE, DE EO IVDICIVM DABO. The iudicium here referred to was the condictio certae pecuniae, the formula of which has already been given*. We know that mutuvm, could be applied to other fungible things besides money, such as wine, oil or seeds, and in those cases the remedy must have been the condictio triticaria'^. FoENVS NAVTIGVM {Bdveiov vavTiKov). A con- tract very similar to mviuvm,, which we know to have existed in the Republican period, since we find it mentioned by Seruius Sulpicius * and entered into by Cato', was foeniis nauticum, a form of marine insurance resembling bottomry^. It consisted of a money loan (pecunia traiecticia) to be paid back by the borrower, — ^invariably the owner of a ship, — 1 Cic. Rose. Com. 4. 13. 2 As in Pers. 1. 1. 37; Merc. 1. 1. 58; Pseud. 1. 5. 91. s Voigt, I. N. IV. 616. •* p. 104. » 12 Dig. 1. 2. 8 22 Dig. 2. 8. ' Plutarch, Cat. Mai. 21. ' Camazza, Dir. Com. p. 176 ff. Digitized by Microsoft® FOENVS NAVTIGVM. 183 only in the event of the ship's safe return from her voyage. A slave or freedman of the lender apparently went with the ship to guard against fraud'; but there was no hjrpothecation of the ship, as in a modem bottomry bond. The contract resembled mutuum in being made without formality; but its marked peculiarities were: (i) That it was confined to loans of money, (ii) And to loans from insurers to ship-owners, (iii) And because of the great risk it was not a gratuitous loan, but always bore interest at a very high rate ^ It is, however, quite possible that this interest was not originally allowed as a part of the formless contract, but that it was customary, as Labeo states ', to stipulate for a severe poena in case the loan was not returned. If that be so, the stipu- l&tory poena spoken of by Seruius and Labeo must have been the forerunner in the Republican period of the onerous interest mentioned by Paulus'' as an inherent part of this contract in his day. Art. 2. CoMMODATVM. The next three real contracts are not mentioned by Gains, who appa- rently took his classification fi-om Seruius Sulpicius, and it therefore seems certain that in the time of Seruius and during the Republic they were not re- garded as contracts, but as mere pacta praetoria. Commodatum was the same transaction as mutuum applied to a different object. In mutuum there was a gratuitous loan of money or other res fungihilis, 1 Plut. Gat. 1. 0.; 45 Dig. 1. 122 fr. 1. ■' 22 Big. 2. 7. ' 22 Big. 2. 9. " 22 Big. 2. 7. Digitized by Microsoft® 184 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. whereas in commodatum the gratuitous loan was one of a res nonfungihilis ' Both were originally acts of friendship, as their gratuitous nature implies. Plautus shows us that in his day the loan of money was not distinguished from that of other objects, for he uses commodare^ and iitendwm dare^ in speaking of a money loan, as well as in describing genuine cases of commodatum. We do not, however, discover from Plautus that commo- datum, was actionable in his time, as mmiuwrn clearly was. Vtendmn dare, we may note, is in his plays a more usual term than commodare *. If it be asked why the condictio was not extended to commodatum as it was to mutwu/m, the answer is that the latter always gave rise to a liquidated debt, whereas in a case of commodatum the damages had first to be judicially ascertained, and for this purpose the con- dictio was manifestly not available. The earliest mention of commodatum as an action- able agreement occurs in the writings of Quintus Mucins Scaeuola (ob. A.v.c. 672) quoted by Ulpian" and Gellius *. Cicero significantly omits to mention it in his list of bonae fidei contracts, and the Lex lulia Municipalis (a.v.c. 709) contains no allusion to it'. The peculiar rules of the agreement seem to have become fixed at an early date. Quintus Mucins Scaeuola is said to have decided that culpa leuis ^ e.g. a scyphus, Plaut. Asin. 2. i. 38 or a chlamys, Men. i. i. 94. 2 Asin. 3. 3. 135. « Persa, 1. 3. 37. * Aul. 1. 2. 18 ; Bvd. 3. 1. 9. » 13 Dig. 6. 5. « VI. 15. 2. ' Bruns, Font. p. 107. Digitized by Microsoft® AGE OF COMMODATVM. 185 should be the measure of responsibility required from the bailee (is cui commodatur), and to have established the rule as to furtum usus, in cases where the res commodata was improperly used. It seems therefore probable that the Praetor recognised commodatum at first as a pactum praetoriwn, and granted for its protection an actio in factum, with the following formula : Si paret A™ Agerium N" Negidio rem qua de agitur commodasse (or utendam dedisse) eamque A" Agerio redditam non esse, quanti ea res erit, tantam pecuniam N"^ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. The agreement between bailor and bailee pro- bably did not come to be regarded as a regular contract until after the time of Cicero. We must therefore place the introduction of the actio commo- dati at least as late as A.v.c. 710, and by so doing we explain Cicero's silence. Whatever conclusion we shall arrive at as to depositum must almost neces- sarily be taken as applying to commodatum, also. They both had double forms of action in the time of Gaius\ neither is mentioned by Cicero, and Scaeuola evidently dealt with them both together. Hence their simultaneous origin seems almost certain. The actio commodati is said to have been instituted by a Praetor Pacuuius'', who, like Plau- tus, used the words utendum dare instead of com- modare. The terms of his Edict must therefore have been: 1 IV. 47. 2 13 Dig. 6. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 186 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. QVOD QVIS VTENDVM DEDISSE DICETVR, DE EO IVDICIVM DABOl The author of this Edict was formerly supposed by Voigt to be Pacuuius Antistius Labeo", the father of Labeo the jurist ; but this statement has recently been withdrawn' on the ground that this Pacuuius, having been a pupil of Seruius Sulpicius *, could not have been Praetor as early as the time of Quintus Mucius. If however the above theory as to the dates be correct, Voigt's former view may be sound : Q. Mucius may have been speaking of the actionable pactum, while Pacuuius may have been the author of the true contract. The aMio com- modati directa had a formula as follows: Qiiod A' Agerius N" Negidio rem q. d. a. commodauit (or utendam dedit) quidquid oh earn rem M™ Negi- dium A" Agerio dare facere praestare oportet ex fide bona, eius iudex N"^ Negidiwm A' Agerio con- demna. s. n. p. a. It was doubtless in this form that the action on a commodatum was unknown to Cicero. He must have been familiar only with the actio in factvmi, and for that very reason he must have regarded com/modatwm not as a contract, but as a pactum conuentum. Art. 3. Depositvm. The most general word denoting the bestowal of a trust by one person upon another was commendare', and Voigt has shown' that corrvmendaiumh was the technical term 1 I. N. III. 969. 2 I. N. in. 969 note 149G. » B. HG. i. 622 note 25. * 1 Dig. 2. 2. 44. ' Plant. Trin. 4. 3. 76 ; Cio. Fam. ii. 6. 5 ; 16 Diff. 3. 24 ; Cio. Fin. III. 2. 9. « R. RG. i. App. 5. Digitized by Microsoft® OBIGIN OF DEPOSITVM. 187 for a particular kind of pactum. If the object of commendatio '■ was the performance of some service, the relation was a case of mandatwm'^ : if its object was the keeping of some article in safe custody, the relation was described as depositvmi^. This case clearly shows how arbitrary is the distinction drawn by the Roman jurists between Real and Consensual Contract. Though starting, as we have seen, from the same point, mandatum came to be classed as a consensual, and depositv/m as a real contract. This was simply because the latter dealt, while the former did not deal, with the possession of a definite res. Depositum distinctly appears in Plautus* as an agreement by which some object is placed in a man's custody and committed to his care, though deponere is not the word generally used by Plautus to denote the act of depositing. He prefers the phrase seruandimi dare, corresponding to utendvmi dare, which we found to be his usual expression for commodatum'. These very words, semandum dare, were also used by Quintus Mucins Scaeuola in dis- cussiDg depositum ', but we cannot ascertain from his language whether or not the actio depositi was already known to him. He may merely have been discussing an actionable pactum,. Nor can we infer from any passage of Plautus the existence of depositum as a contract in his time. He seems 1 Cic. Fin. III. 20. 65. 2 Plant. Merc. 5. 1. 6. 3 16 Dig. 3. 24 ; Plant. Merc. 2. 1. 22. * Bacch. 2. 3. 72. 6 Merc. 2. 1. 14 ; Cure. 2. 8. 66 ; Bacch. 2. 8. 10. 8 Gell. VI. 15. 2. Digitized by Microsoft® 188 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. rather to represent it, as Cicero does ', in the light of a friendly relation based simply on fides '^-j and in most of the Plautine passages the transaction is that which was afterwards known as depositum irregulare, i.e. the deposit of a package containing money either at a banker's ', or with a friend * Some have thought that there must have been an action in Plautus' time for the protection of such important trusts °, but Demelius° points out that the actio furti (to which Paulus alludes as actio ex catosa depositi) would have afforded ample protection in most cases; and it would be extremely rash to infer that either commodatum or d&positwm was actionable in the sixth century of the City. At first sight it even looks as though depositum, was not protected by any action in the days of Cicero. The passages in which he mentions it' appear to treat the restoration of the res deposita rather as a moral than a legal duty. Similarly where he enumerates the bonae fidei actions', where he mentions the persons qui bonam fidem praestare debent ', and where he describes the indicia de fide mala'^', he entirely leaves out the actio depositi and does not make the slightest allusion to depositum. But all this is equally true of commodatum^. And since we have the clearest evidence that com- modatum. was actionable in the time of Quintus 1 2 Verr. it. 16. 36. ^ Merc. 2. 1. 14. 5 Cure. 2. 3. 66. * Bacch. 2. 3. 101. » Costa, Dir. Priv. p. 320. « Z. fur RG. ii. 224. ' Farad, iii. 1. 21 ; Off. i. 10. 31 ; iii. 25. 95. 8 Off. III. 17. 70. 9 Top. 10. 42. " N. D. III. 30. 7. " Gai. iv. 47. Digitized by Microsoft® LATENESS OF ACTIO DEPOSIT!. 189 Mucius ScaeuolaS we can hardly avoid the con- viction that depositurn also was actionable in his day by means of an actio in fojctvmi, whereas the actio depositi was not introduced, as Voigt holds, till the beginning of the eighth century==- This theory of development, already applied to mandatum and societas, has the advantage, not only of explaining why commodatwm and depositvmi were not numbered among hoTiae fidei contractus, but also of accounting for the existence in Gains' day of their double formulae which have puzzled so many jurists'. We may then believe that depositurn was first made actionable between A.v.c. 650 and 670 as a pactum praetorium, and with the protection of an actio in factum concepta as given by Gains: Si paret A™ Agerium apud N™ Negidiwm mensam argenteam deposuisse eamque dolo N^ Negidii A" Agerio red- ditam nan esse, quanti ea res erit, tantam pecuniam, iudex, N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemnato. s. n. p. a. This formula was doubtless the only one pro- vided for depositumi down to the end of Cicero's career. But about A.v.c. 710^ juristic interpre- tation began to regard commodatvmi and depositurn as genuine contracts iuris ciuilis, and thereupon a second formula was iutroduced into the Edict, with- out disturbing the earlier one, so that depositurn, like commodatwm, was finally recognised as a contract. 1 13 Dig. 6. 5. " Earn. EG. i. 623. * See Muirhead's Gaim, p. 293 note. * 41 Dig. 2. 3. 18 ; 16 Dig. 31. 1. 46 ; Trebatius was trib. pleb. A.V.C. 707. Digitized by Microsoft® 190 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM. We know that the Praetor's Edict by which this change was brought about ran somewhat thus : QVOD NEQVE TVMVLTVS NEQVE INCENDII NEQVE RVINAE NEQVE NAVFRAGII CAVSA DEPOSITVM SIT IN SIMPLVM, EAEVM AVTEM RERVM QVAB SVPRA COMPREHENSAE SVNT IN IPSVM IN DVPLVM, IN HEREDEM EIVS QVOD DOLO MALO EACTVM ESSE DICETVR QVI MORTWS SIT IN SIMPLVM, QVOD IPSIVS IN DVPLVM IVDICIVM DABO'. The penalty of dwplwm shows that, where the depositwn had been compelled by adverse cir- cumstances, a violation of the contract was regarded as peculiarly disgraceful and treacherous. In other cases, where the depositwn was made under ordinary circumstances, the amount recovered was simplwm, and the new formula must have been that given by Gaius " as follows : Quod A' Agenus apud N™ Negi- dium mensam argenteam, deposuit qua de re agitur, quidquid oh earn rem JSf™ Negidium A" Agerio dare facere oportet ex fide bona, eius index N™ Negidiv/m A" Agerio condemnato. s. n. p. a. Art. 4. PiGNVS. The giving and taking of a pledge appears in Plautus as a means of securing a promise, but seems then to have belonged to the class of friendly acts which the law did not con- descend to enforce. In Gaptiui^ for instance, the slave who had been pledged is demanded in a purely in- formal way, and in Rudens^ pignus is a mere token given to prove that the giver is speaking the truth. Its connection with arrhabo is very close. Each served to show that an agreement was seriously 1 16 Dig. 3. 1. ••' IV. 47. » 5. 1. 18. • 2. 7. 23. Digitized by Microsoft® ^0270 PIGNERATICIA. 191 meant by the parties, or was a means of securing credit as a substitute for money', and if the agree- ment was broken, the pignus or arrhabo was doubtless kept as compensation. This practice of giving pawns or pledges was probably of great antiquity, but we hear nothing of it from legal sources, simply because it was an institution founded on mores alone. It pro- bably applied only to moveables and res nee mancipi\ for res mancipi could be dealt with by a pactvmi fiduciae annexed to mancipatio. Gaius ' derives the word from pugnuTn, because a pledge was handed over to the pledgee ; but the correct derivation is doubtless from the same root as pactum, pepigi, Pacht, Pfand*. Pignus must then have meant a thing fixed or fastened, and so a security. And this derivation suits the word in the phrase pignoris capio equally well, without leading us to suppose that the custom of giving a pledge was in any way derived from the pignoris capio of the legis actio system. We do not know when pignus became a contract, though it certainly was so before the end of the Republic. Long before being recognised as such it doubtless enjoyed the protection of an actio in factum, with a formula as follows : Si paret A^ Agerium N" Negidio ratem q. d. a. oh pecuniam debitam pignori dedisse, eamque pecuniam solutam, eoue nomine satis- factum esse, aut per N™ Negidium stetisse quominus soluatur, eamque ratem q. d. a. A" Agerio redditam rum esse, quanti ea res erit, tantam, &c.^ In course 1 Bechmann, Kauf, ii. 416. ''■ 50 Big. 16. 238. ' ibid. * Dernburg, FJr. i. p. 49 ; Beitr. zur vrgl. Sprachforsch. ii. p. 49. ' Lenel, Ed. perp. p. 201. Digitized by Microsoft® 192 CONTRACTS OF THE IVS GENTIVM, of time the actio pigneraticia was introduced as an alternative remedy, and Ubbelohde ' has argued that since its place in the edict was between commodatum and depositum, the Praetor must have introduced the actio pign&raiicia after the actio com/modati and before the actio depositi ; which seems a very plausi- ble conjecture. We have no direct evidence of the existence of an actio pigneraticia earlier than the time of Alfenus Varus, a jurist of the later Re- public"''; it is not mentioned by Cicero; in short everything points to the origin of the contract of pigrms as corresponding in age to that of commo- datwm and depositwm. The language of the Edict by which pignus was made a contract has not survived, while the formula of its actio pigneraticia resembled of course that of the actio depositi, and need not therefore be given. Though pignus was doubtless a very inadequate security from the point of view of the pledgor, since it might at any time be alienated or destroyed, it is the only form which appears to be common in Plautus, and of fiducia he shows us not a trace '- Pignus seems to have been much used for making wagers, and pignore certare was probably as common as sponsione certare ^ which we treated of in a pre- vious article. The contracts of a kindred nature which seem to have arisen even sooner than pignus will be discussed in the next chapter. 1 6. der ben. Bealcont. p. 62. 2 13 jjjgr. 7. 30. 3 Costa, Dir. Priv. p. 262. * Bekker, Akt. i. 253. Digitized by Microsoft® CHAPTER VIII. CONTRACTS NOT USUALLY CLASSIFIED AS SUCH. Art. 1. FiDVCiA. We have examined in a former chapter the early origin of the pactwm fidudae^, a formless agreement annexed to a solemn conveyance, by which the transferee of the object conveyed as security agreed to reconvey, as soon as the debt was paid, or whenever a given condition should arise. As a result of the Edict Pacta conuenta, and before Cicero's time'', this pactum became en- forceable by the actio fiduciae. This action was in factum, like the others of its class, and its function was to award damages, but it could not otherwise compel the actual recon- veyance of the object. Its formula must have been worded as follows^ : Si paret A™ Ageriwm N" Negidio fwndum quo de agitur oh pecuniam debitam fiduciae causa mancipio dedisse, eamque pecuniam solutam eoue nomine satis- f actum esse, aut per N™' Negidium stetisse quominus solueretur, eumque fwndum redditum non esse, nego- 1 Supra, p. 78. '^ Cie. Off. in. 15. 61. 3 Lenel, Ed. Perp. p. 233. B. E. 13 Digitized by Microsoft® 194 CONTEACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. tiumue ita actum non esse ut inter honos T)ene agier oportet et sine fraudatione, quanti ea res erit tantwm pecuniam index N™ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. The peculiar clause "ut inter honos bene agier oportet"'^ virtually made this a bonae fidei action. That fact may perhaps explain vfhyfiduda was never protected by a formula in ius coTicepta, and hence was never regarded as a true contract. Art. 2. Hypotheca. We have seen that there were two ways in which a tangible security might be given: (i) the object might be conveyed with a pactum fiduciae, providing that it should be recon- veyed on the fulfilment of a certain condition, or else (ii) the mere detention of the object might be granted on similar terms. In the former case the pledge or its value could be recovered by the actio fiduciae, in the latter by the actio pigne- raticia whose origin we have just discussed. But neither fiducia nor pignus was a contract of pledge pure and simple; each consisted of an agreement plus a delivery of the object. The abstract conception of mortgage, i.e. pledging by mere agreement, is a distinct advance upon both these methods. The contract which embodied this form of pledge was known as hypotheca ; and as its name indicates it was borrowed from the Greeks, from whom the Romans also took the Lex Rhodia de iactu and the foeitms nauticum. Precisely the same contract is found in the speeches of Demos- 1 Cic. Top. 17. 66. Digitized by Microsoft® ORIGIN OF HYPOTHECA. 195 thenes' under the name of v-trodr)Kr\, which could he applied to moveables or immoveables, and even to articles not yet in existence. The Romans how- ever regarded hypotheca not as a contract but as a pactum. It is quite certain that a legal conception so refined as the pactum hypothecae could not have had a place in the legal system of the XII Tables. There are passages in Festus" and Dionysius" in which the words si quid pignoris and eveyypat^eiv have been supposed to indicate the existence of some such practice at an early period. But the evidence is much too vague to supply trustworthy data, and we may confidently assert that mortgage was unknown to the early law*. Accordingly, we find that hy- potheca was introduced and made actionable by slow degrees. Its popular name was pignus oppo- situm, as distinct from pignus depositum, the ordinary pignut above described. Its LQtroduction seems to have been one of the many legal innovations produced by the large immi- gration of strangers into Rome after the Second Punic War. These strangers must generally have become tenants of Roman landlords, since the lack of ius commercii prevented their buying lands or houses, and in order to secure his rent, the only resource open to the landlord was to take the household goods of these tenants as security. Such household goods {inuecta illata) probably constituted in most cases the only wealth of the foreign immigrant, conse- 1 Dernburg, Pfdr. i. p. 69. ^ s.u. nancitor. " VI. 29. * Dernburg, Pfdr. i. 55. 13—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 196 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. quently the landlord could not remove them, and the method of pignus was not available. The ex- pedient which suggested itself was that the tenant should pledge his goods without removal, by means of a simple agreement. The relation thus created was the original form of hypotheca and was precisely analogous to that of a modern chattel mortgage. As the idea was introduced by foreigners ', it was very natural that this agreement of pledge should have received a foreign name. Another class to whom the new expedient was applied were the free agricultural tenants (coloni) whose sole wealth often consisted of their tools and other agricultural stock^. The necessity of making a pledge without removal is obvious in their case also. I. It was for the protection of landlords that a Praetor Saluius introduced the interdictum Salui- anum, which seems to have been the first legal recognition that hypotheca received. Its date is not known. Formerly the Praetor Saluius lulianus, author of the Edictum perpetuum, was regarded as the inventor of this interdict, but his own language in the Digest^ contradicts this supposition. The most reasonable theory is that the interdict origi- nated before the Edict Pacta conuenta (A.v.c. 627) at about the end of the sixth century. The fact that Plautus knew hypotheca as a mere nudum pactum can hardly be doubted*. It is true that he not only uses, as Terence does a little later ', 1 Dernburg, Pfdr. i. 56. " 4 Big. 15. 3. 1. » 1.S Dig. 7. 22. * Demelius, Z.filr RG. ii. 232. 5 Phorm. 4. 3. 56. Digitized by Microsoft® INTERDIGTVM SALVIANVM. 197 the phrase pignori opponere ' to denote the making of a pledge by mere agreement; but he also men- tions the Greek technical term eTndi^Krj and seems to use hypotheca as a metaphor'^. The testimony to be gathered from these passages does not however prove that hypotheca was actionable'. The contents of the interdictum Saluianum can- not be given with certainty. We only know two things about it : (1) that it was a remedy of limited scope, being available only against the tenant or pledgor, but not against third parties to whom he had transferred or sold or pledged the goods, and (2) that the interdict was prohibitory and forbade the pledgor to prevent the landlord from seizing the objects which had been mortgaged. (1) This first proposition is distinctly stated by a constitution of Gordian", but flatly contradicted by a passage in the Digest *. The latter authority, however, seems open to strong suspicion " and the fact that the actio Seruiana was presumably intro- duced because the interdictum Saluianum was inadequate further goes to prove the correctness of Gordian's constitution. (2) We may be fairly certain that the interdict was prohibitory, like the interdictum utrvbi, and not restitutory, as Huschke would have it'; since the weight of authority is in favour of the former 1 Pseud. 1. 1. 85. * True. 2. 1. i. 3 Costa, Dir. priv. p. 264 ; Dernburg, Pfdr. i. p. 65. * 8 God. 9. 1. = 43 Dig. 33. 1. " Lenel, Z. der Sav. Stiftung, R. A, iii. 181. 7 Studien, p. 398. Digitized by Microsoft® 198 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. view^ We may therefore accept KudorfiPs restora- tion of its formula, which runs as follows*: Si is homo quo de agitur est ex his rebus de quibus inter te et conductorem (colonum, &c. &c.) conuenit, ut quae in eu/m fwndum quo de agitw inducta illata ibi nata factaue essent ea pignori tibi pro mercede eiusfimdi essent, neque ea merces tibi soluta eoue nomine satis- f actum, est aut per te stat quaminu^s soluatur, ita quo- minus eum ducas uim fieri ueto. II. The second remedy introduced to enforce the formless agreement of mortgage was the actio Seruiana, which was far more efficacious. Its author cannot have been Seruius Sulpicius Rufus, the Mend of Cicero, because he never was Praetor Vrbanus, and the action must have existed long before his time. The Praetor who devised it was doubtless one of the many Seruii Sulpicii whose names constantly appear in the fasti consulares, and its age is probably not much less than that of the interdictum Saluianum. The action was certainly younger than the interdict, and an improvement upon it, because the jurists treated the law of mortgage under the head of inter- dict', which indicates that this was the form of the original remedy. We may be sure that the interdict is older than the Edict Pacta conuenta, for otherwise it would not have been needed. And as soon as pa(Aa were thus legally recognised, it is safe to say that a more perfect remedy for hypotheca was sure ' Dernburg, Pfdr. p. 59; Bachofen, Pfdr. p. 13; Keller, Re- cemion. p. 977 and Eudorff, Pfandkl. p. 210 ; Lenel, Ed. Perp. p. 394. ■ 2 Pfandkl. p. 209. Of. Budorff, Ed. Perp. 282. ' Dernburg, Pfdr. i. p. 61. Digitized by Microsoft® ACTIO SERVIANA. 199 to be devised. The probability is then that the actio Seruiana was one of the first products of the Edict Pacta conuenta, partly because we know that the interdict was an imperfect remedy, partly because hypotheca was much in vogue at that early date. Thus we may gather from Plautus' allusions that hypotheca was already in a well developed state about A.v.c. 570. Cato the Censor^ also seems to have alluded to it, and Caec. Statins {oh. A.v.c. 586), as cited by Festus", unquestionably did so. The curious circumstance that Cicero should have mentioned it only twice ^ may perhaps be accounted for by the fact that pignus in its looser sense was always a synonym for hypotheca *, and as he mentions it so seldom in its Greek form, we may suppose that the term hypotheca was then only just coming into general use. We know that pignus in the narrower sense was distinguished by Ulpian from hypotheca as sharply as we distinguish a pawn from a mortgage ^, but the earlier writers lead us to infer that the term pignus oppositum, or simply pignus, was origi- nally the equivalent of hypotheca. The effect of the actio Seruiana was probably a mere enlargement of the scope of the interdictwm ■ Saluianum, giving the landlord a legal hold upon the inuecta illata of his tenant even in the possession of third parties. But since the right of thus pledging by agreement was as yet recognised only as between the colonus or the house-tenant and his landlord, 1 jj. i{. 146. ^ s.u. reluere. 3 Att. n. 17 and Fam. xiii. 56. ■* 20 Dig. 1. 5. » 13 Dig. 7. 9. Digitized by Microsoft® 200 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. hypotheca was a transaction still confined to a small class. III. A final improvement was effected, perhaps shortly after the one just mentioned, when the Praetor granted an action on. the analogy of the actio Seruiana, upon all agreements of pledge of whatever description. From the creation of this action, known as cuctio quasi Seruiana ^ or hypothecaria ", or simply Seruiana^, dated the introduction of a law of mort- gage applicable to objects of all kinds. The name hypothecaria, which we find applied only to the last of these three remedies, implies either that this was the only action available for all forms of hypotheca, or else that the Greek term was not introduced until the contract had thus become general. The formula of the CKtio quasi Seruiana or hypo- thecaria was of course in factum concepta *, because the pactum hypothecae never was treated as a con- tractus iuris ciuilis, though it became in reality as binding as any contract. The words are restored by Lenel° as follows, in an action by the mortgagee against a third party : Si paret inter A™ Agerium et Ludum Titium, conuenisse ut ea res qua de agitur A° Agerio pignori hypothecaeue esset propter pecuniam debitam, eamque rem tunc cum conueniebat in bonis D Titiifuisse, eamque pecuniam neque solutam neque eo nomine satisfactum esse neque per A^ Agerium, stare quominus soluatur, nisi eares A" Agerio arbitratu-tuo 1 4 Inst. 6. 7. 2 16 Dig. 1. 13. ' Bachofen, Pfdr. p. 28. * Ed. perp. p. 397 ; cf. Dernburg, Pfdr. i. p. 78. ' ib. p. 81 ; cf. Budorfl, Ed. perp. 234. Digitized by Microsoft® AQTIO HYPOTHEOARIA. 201 restituetur, quanti ea res erit, tantam pecuniam index N'" Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s, n. p. a. No mortgage can be of much practical use unless it empowers the creditor to sell the thing pledged, so as to cover his loss. But it is evident that the mere pledgee or mortgagee could have had no in- herent right to sell or convey what did not belong to him. This was an advantage possessed by fiduoia, since the property was fully conveyed and could therefore be disposed of as soon as the condition was broken. The only way out of the difficulty both in pignus and hypotheca was to make a condition of sale part of the original agreement. This was un- necessary under the Empire ^ when the power of sale came to be implied in every hypotheca, but during the Republic the power had to be explicitly re- served, or else the vendor was liable for conversion (furtumy. Even Gains " speaks as though a pactum de uendendo was usual in his time. Labeo describes a sale eoc pacta conuento^, but the usual name for the clause of the agreement containing the power of sale was lex ccmimissoria. When it became possible to insert such a clause is uncertain, but Demburg seems right in maintaining that, as the lex commis- soria was known to Labeo and to the far more ancient Greek law, it must certainly have been customary at Rome long before the end of the Republic. 1 13 Dig. 7. 4. 2 47 Dig. 2. 74 ; Demburg, Pfdr. i. p. 91. ^ n. 64. * 20 Dig. 1. 35. = Pfdr. I. p. 86 as against Baehofen, Pfdr. p. 157. Digitized by Microsoft® 202 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. The custom of committing hypothecae to writing (tabulae), which is indicated by Gaius', doubtless pre- vailed also in the Republican period, the object of the writing being simply to facilitate proof When we translate hypotheca by the English word mortgage, we must not forget that the latter denotes technically a conveyance defeasible by con- dition subsequent, closely resembling ^cZwcia, where- as the former denoted the mere creation of a lien. On the other hand it is true that our modem mortgage has lost its original resemblance to fidma, and has now become almost identical with hypotheca. Art. 3. Praediatvea. This was a peculiar form of suretyship which the Roman jurists never treated as a contract, though it doubtless had a very ancient origin. It was connected with the public emtiones and locationes, and was the regular method by which contractors or undertakers of public work gave bond to do their work properly. The transaction resembled the giving of sponsores in private law. The friends of the contractor who were willing to be his sureties (praedes) appeared before the Praetor or other magistrate, and entered into a verbal contract by which they bound them- selves with all that they possessed. The magistrate, we are told, asked each surety " Praesne es?" and the surety answered "Praes"\ This has every appearance of having been a formal contract like sponsio, and it is difficult to accept the view of Mommsen ^ who considers that the publicity of the » 20 Dig. 1. 4 ; 22 Dig. 4. 4. 2 Paul. Diao. s.u. Praes. ' Stadtr. von Salpema, p. 468. Digitized by Microsoft® PRAEDIATVRA. 203 transaction leads us to infer its formless character. If we follow him in assuming that praedes and praedia were purely public institutions, how can we explain the existence of the praedes litis et uindici- arum, who certainly appeared in private suits ', and how can we understand those passages in Plautus and Cicero which clearly refer to praedes and praedia in private transactions ^ ? If then we deny to prae- diatura an exclusively public character, we must class it with sponsio and uadimonium as another formal mode of giving security. The etymology which explains the word praes as being the adverbial form of praesto is undoubtedly false '. Ihering and Goppert ■* suppose that it comes from the same root as praedium, and means one who undertakes a liability. But in the Lex agraria the spelling is praeuides instead of praedes, and this indicates rather that the true derivation is from prae and uas ', in the sense of " one who comes forth and binds himself verbally "^ Pott' thinks that uas was the generic term for surety, and that praes was a composite word meaning a surety who makes good (praestare) what he undertakes. Where the derivation is so uncertain no safe conclusion can be arrived at, and the origin of the contract must, in this case as in that of the primitive vadimonium, remain an enigma. ' Cf. aduersariw, Gai. iv. 16, 94. 2 Plaut. Men. 4. 2. 28 ; Cio. Att. xiii. 3. 1. 3 Eivier, Untersuch. p. 29. * Z.fiir RG. iv. p. 26.^. ' Fas bomfari, or uas from a root meaning " to bind." 8 Dernbur'g, P/dr. i. 27 ; Eivier, Untersueh. p. 14. ' Etym. Forsch. iv. p. 417. Digitized by Microsoft® 204 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. The obligation of the praes was enforced by com- pulsory sale, the details of which we unfortunately do not know. The expression praedes uendere^ shows approximately how the right was enforced^, but it is uncertain whether this ^ meant to sell the property of the surety, or merely to sell the claim of the State against him K Besides the personal responsibility thus assumed by the praes, there was another kind of security known as praedium^ which the principal might be required to give. If the praedes furnished by him were not sufficient, praediwm might be required as an additional safeguard'; but we also find that praedes or praedia might be separately given'. The form in which a bond of praedia had to be made was a written acknowledgment in the Treasury (praediorum apud aerarium subsignatio), and the only object capable of serving or being pledged as a praedium was landed property owned by a Roman citizen, and possessing all the qualities of a res mancipi^. Hence the seciirity of praedia could not in many instances have been available, for the whole of solwm prouinciale and the holdings of ager publicus in the possession of occupatorii would of course have been excluded. The amount of ' Cio. Phil. 11. 31. 78 ; aes Malac. cap. 64-5. 2 Dernburg, Pfdr. i. p. 28. ' Cic. 2 Verr. i. 54. 142. * Goppert, Z.filr EG. iv. p. 288. ' Lex agraria of a.v.c. 643 ; Lex Put. parieti faciendo, Bruns, Font. p. 272, aes Malac. cap. 64. ' ae» Malac. cap. 60. ' e.g. Lex Acilia repet. 61, 66, 67, and Festus s.u. quadrantal, 8 Cic. Place. 32. 80. Digitized by Microsoft® PRAEDIORVM SVBSIGNATIO. 205 praedia which had to be given was entirely in the magistrate's discretion ^ and to help him in his decision we find that there existed praediorum cognitores^ who were probably persons appointed to assess the value of praedia, and responsible to the State if their information was wrong. As to the nature of the transaction effected by praediorum subsignatio, there can be no doubt that the old theory held by Savigny and others is incor- rect ', and that the State did not in virtue of svbsig- natio become absolute owner of the praedia. Rivier and Demburg * have demonstrated that the State merely acquired a lien, and that praediorum sub- signatio was therefore a species of mortgage. The classical sources fully support this view", and it is certain that while the property was subject to this lien its owner still had the right to sell it and to exercise other rights of ownership*. A public sale (uenditio praediorum) followed closely no doubt upon the default of the debtor, but did not neces- sarily accompany the sale of the goods of the praedes^ (uenditio praedium). At Rome the former sale was made by the praefecti aerario, and in the Lex Mala- citana the duumvirs or decuriones are empowered to make it °. A peculiarity of the sale of praedia was that the ' Lex agraria, 73-4 ; Bruns, Font. p. 84. 2 aes Malac. cap. 65. 3 Savigny Heid. Jahrsch. 1809, p. 268 ; Walter, E. G. p. 587 ; Hugo, R. G. 449. * Pfdr. 1. p. 33. ° Varro L. L. v. 40 ; Lex agraria, 74. 8 50 Dig. 17. 205. ^ Gai. ii. 61 ; Cie. 2 Verr. i. 55. 144. 8 cap. 64; Bruns, Font. p. 146. Digitized by Microsoft® 206 CONTKACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. dominiwm residing in the owner became instantly transferred to the praediaior or purchaser from the State, without any act on the owner's part. The only advantage reserved to the dispossessed owner was an exceptional right of recovering his property from the purchaser by usurec&ptio, i.e. conscious usucapio S one of the few instances in which it was possible to exercise usucapio otherwise than with a bona fide colour of title. In this case, as the praedia were always land, the statutory period of two years was necessary to complete the adverse possession. The lex praediatoria mentioned in the aes Malacitanum" has been thought to be a statute of unknown date; but it more probably denotes some collection of traditional terms used in praediatura and analogous to a lex uenditionis in a contract of sale °. The restoration of "praediatoria " in Gains' is doubtful, and "censoria" seems much to be pre- ferred. The operation of praediatura as a general lien on all the property of the praes was probably re- cognised in the Republican period, although Dem- burg° has doubts on this point. Such a lien is found in the Lex Malacitana in the time of Domitian, but this may have been an extension to the public aerarium of the general hypotheca belonging to the Imperial Fiscus. At any rate, there is no evidence that the lien did not exist in our period ; and if it 1 Gai. II. 61. « cap. 64. 3 Boecking, Rom. Priv. B. 294. * IV. 28. 5 Pfdr. X. p. 42. Digitized by Microsoft® ACTIO QVOD irssv. 207 did, we can readily see that the security of praedia- tura was superior to that of sponsio. It is perhaps natural that the subject of praedes and praedia should be obscure, for the complicated nature of the law of praediatura is attested by Cicero \ who states that certain lawyers made it a special study. Art. 4. AcTiONES ADiECTiciAE. Besides intro- ducing the actio mandati, the Praetor's edict en- larged the scope of agency by instituting several other important actions. These were the actiones quod iussu, exercitoria, institoria, tributoria, de peculio and de in rem uerso. In all of them alike the Prae- tor's object was to fasten responsibility on some superior with whose consent, or on whose behalf, contracts had been made by an inferior. They are known as actiones adiecticiae, because they were considered as supplementing the ordinary actions which could be brought against the inferior himself ^ As they made the principal liable on the contracts of a subordinate, it is plain that they must have been a most useful substitute for the complete law of agency which the Romans always lacked. The fact that they all had formulae in ius conceptae points to a late origin, but they all doubtless origi- nated before the end of the Republic. (1) The actio quod iussu was an action in which a son or slave, who had made a contract at the bidding of his pater familias, was treated as a mere conduit pipe, and by which the obligation was directly imposed on the pater familias who had 1 Balb. 20. 45. = 14 Dig. 1. 5. fr. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 208 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. authorized it. Since Labeo mentioned the action as though its practice was well developed in his day ', we may fairly suppose that iussus was made action- able in Republican times. The formula was as follows : Quod iussu N^ Negidii A" Agerius Gaio, cum is in potestate N'' Negidii esset, togam uendidit qua de re agitur, quidquid oh earn rem Oaium jUium A° Agerio dare facere oportet ex fide hona, eius iudex iV™ Negidium patrem A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a. Here the express comniand of the superior was the source of his obligation. (2) The actio exercitoria was an action in which a ship owner or charterer {exercitor) was held directly responsible for the contracts of the ship master " (ma- gister nauis). Its formula probably ran as follows: Quod A^ Agerius de Lmio Titio magistro eius nauis quam N' Negidius exercebat, eius rei causa in quam L' Titius ibi praepositus fuit, incertum stipulatus est qua de re agitur, quidquid oh earn rem N'^ Negidium A" Agerio praestare oportet ex fide bona eius N™' Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a.- It was known to Ofilius in the eighth century of the city*, and was very probably even older than his day. The necessities of trade were obviously the source from which this particular form of agency sprang, because in an age of great commercial activity, when even bills of lading were not yet introduced, it was expedient that the delivery of goods or the 1 15 Dig. 4. 1. fr. 9. ^ x4 Big. 1. 1. ' Baron, Abh. aus dem B. C. P. ii. 181. * 14 Dig. 1. 1. fr. 9. Digitized by Microsoft® ACTIO INSTITORIA. 209 making of contracts by the master should be equi- valent to a direct transaction with the ship owner himself. (3) The actio institoria no doubt had a like commercial origin. This was an action by which the person who employed a manager (institor) in a busiuess from which he drew the profits, was made liable for the debts and contracts of the manager. This action was known as early as the days of Seruius Sulpicius^, and its formula closely resem- bled that of the actio exerdtoria. The difference between these two and the actio quod iussu con- sisted simply in the fact that the iiissus or autho- rization was special in the one case, and general in the other two. In the actiones exercitoria and insti- toria an implied general authority was ascribed to the agent in virtue of his praepositio^, whereas in the actio quod iussu the agent had only an express special authority. Thus the magister nauis and the institor were genuine instances of general agents ; and we find therefore, as we should have expected, that the acts of the magister and institor only bound the master when strictly within the scope of their authority'. This is an excellent instance of the manner in which Mercantile Law has developed the same rules in ancient as in modem times. (4) The actio tributoria was that by which a master was compelled to pay over* to the creditors of a son or slave trading with his consent whatever 1 14 Dig. 3. 5. fr. 1. 2 46 Dig. 3. 18 ; Oosta, Azioni ex. p. 40. ' 14 Dig. 1. 1. fr. 7. •* tribui, 14 Dig. 4. 5. 5. B. E. 14 Digitized by Microsoft® 210 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. profits he had received from the business. The formula ran thus : Quod J.' Agerius de L" Titio qui in potestate N'' Negidii est, cum is sciente N" Negidia merce peculiari negotiaretur, -infiertum stipulatus est qua de re agitur, quidquid ex ea merce et quod eo nomine receptum est ob earn rem iV™ Negidium .4." Agerio tribuere oportet, eius dumtaxat in id quod minus^ dolo malo N^ Negidii A' Agerius tribuit, N'^ Negidium A" Agerio condemna. s. n. p. a*. This action was mentioned by Labeo ' and was there- fore probably as old as the other actions of this class. The knowledge and tacit approval of the superior were here the source of his obligation. (5) The actiones de peculio and de in rem uerso were proceedings by which the master was required to make good any obligation contracted by his son or slave, to the extent of the son's or slave's peculium, or of such gain as had accrued to himself {in rem uersum) from the contract. Their peculiarity, as Gaius has told us and as a recent writer conclu- sively shows*, was that they had one formula with an alternative condemnatio, which may be recon- structed as follows : Quod A' Agerius de Lwdo Titio cum is in potestate JV* Negidii esset, incertmn stipula- tus est qua de re agitur, quidquid ob earn rem Lucius Titius A" Agerio praestare oportet ex fde bona, eius iudex N'^ Negidium A" Agerio, dumtaxat de peculio quod penes N"^ Negidium est, uel siquid in rem N* Negidii inde versv/m est, condemna. s. n. p. a. This » 14 Dig. 7. 3. " Baron, I. c. p. 176. ■< 14 Dig. 4. 7. * Baron, I. e. pp. 136-69 ; cf. Lenel, Ed. perp. p. 225. Digitized by Microsoft® GONSTJTVTVM. 211 formula might be so modified that the actio de peculio and the actio de in rem uerso could be brought either separately or together. These actions were known to Alfenus Varus^, and it is safe to say that they were introduced some time before the end of the Republic. The knowledge or consent of the superior did not here have to be proved. The difference between the actio tributoria and the actio de peculio was considerable. By the former the master contributed his profits and then shared in the distribution as an ordinary creditor. But by the latter he became a preferred creditor, and deducted from his profits the whole amount owed to him by the son or slave. The peculium in the latter case was in fact only the balance remaining after the debts of the son to him had been satisfied. Art. 5. CoNSTiTVTVM AND Receptvm. To- wards the end of the Republic we find two kinds of formless contract by which a debt could be created, and both of which seem to have sprung fi-om the requirements of Roman commerce ■'. I. Gonstitutmn. The chief characteristics of this contract may be gathered from the constitution by which Justinian ftised together the actio recepticia and the actio pecuniae constitutae\ as well as from allusions in the Digest. It seems to have been a formless pro- mise of payment at a particular date ; depending on the existence of a prior indebtedness to which the 1 15 Dig. 3. 16. == Ihering, Geist iv. 218-220. 3 4 Cod. 18. 2. 14—2 Digitized by Microsoft® 212 CONTBACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. constitutwm became accessory^; unconditional^; en- forced by an actio pecuniae constitutae of Praetorian origin which was in some cases perpetua and in others armalis ; and available to persons of all classes. Constitutwm is discussed by Labeo ', and is men- tioned by Cicero^ in a way which makes it certain that the actio pecuniae constitutae existed in his day. The action originated in the Praetor's Edict", and it was thereby provided with a penal sponsio similar to that of the condictio certae pecuniae. This leads us to infer that pecwnia constituta was treated by the Praetor as analogous to pecunia credita ; es- pecially as Gains • states that pecwnia credita strictly meant only an unconditional obligation to pay money, while we know from Justinian's constitution that unless constitutvmi was unconditional no action would lie. But why should the penal sponsio of the actio pecuniae constitutae have been so much heavier than that of the condictio, namely dimidiae instead of tertian partis ' ? The reason given by Theophilus' is that constitutum, was generally entered into by a debtor in order to gain time for the payment of a debt already due, and that the Praetor instituted this severe action in order to discourage insolvent debtors from this practice. Labeo on the contrary says * that constitutvm, was made actionable in order to enforce the payment of debts not yet due. Both ' li Dig. 5.1. fr. 5 ' God. l.c. » 13 Big. 5. 3. ■» Quint. 5. 18. ' 13 Dig. 5. 16. » in. 124. ' Gai. IT. 171. 8 Paraphr. iv. 6-8. 18 Dig. 5. 3. Digitized by Microsoft® TWO FORMS OF ACTION. 213 Labeo and Theophilus are probably right ', but each takes a one-sided view. The Praetor's aim presu- mably was to enforce the payment of any debt, due or not due, which the debtor had made a renewed promise to pay at a particular date. The breach of a repeated promise (for constitutum always implied a previous promise or indebtedness) was doubtless regarded by the Praetor as a singularly flagrant breach of faith ; and hence he compelled the defen- dant to join in a penal sponsio dimidiae partis. This actio per sponsionem was not however the only remedy for a breach of constitutum. The Digest shows that the usual form of redress was an actio in factum ", which ' probably had a formula as follows : Si paret Nwmeriimi Negidium Aulo Agerio X millia Kal. Ian. se soluturwn constituisse, neque earn pecuniam soluisse, neque per Agerium stetisse quo- minus solueretur, eamque pecuniam cum constituehatur debitam fuisse, quanti ea res est, tantam pecuniam, Nunierium Negidium Aulo Agerio condemna ; and that this actio in factum, existed in Gaius' time as an alternative remedy seems probable from his language in iv. 171. It is not likely that the actio in factum arose simultaneously with the other; and of the two Puchta* is almost certainly right in assigning the earlier date to the actio per spon- sionem, because the custom of sponsione prouocare suggests an ancient origin. This sponsio, like that of the condictio, was praeiudicialis, but it also contained a strongly penal element. Its penal character was » Bruns, Z. f. EG. i. p. 56. » 13 Dig. 5. 16. 2. ' Bruns, loc. cit. p. 59. * Inst. ii. 168. Digitized by Microsoft® 214 CONTRACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. no doubt the reason why the action could not be brought against the heir of the constituens, and why it was annalis. As Bruns has shown, the remedy after one year was probably the actio in factum'^, by which the plain amount of the constitutwm could alone be recovered. Gonstitutvmn could be employed for the renewal of the promisor's own debt {const, debiti proprii), as well as of another man's {const, debiti alieni), and this distinction was early allowed". In the later law it could also be used to reinforce and render actionable an obligatio naturalis. But this feature probably did not exist at the origin of the action", for the Praetor could only have had in mind pecunia eredita, when he inflicted such a heavy penalty. The effect of constitutwm was simply to reinforce the old obligation by supplying a more stringent remedy. It never produced novation as stipulatio or expensi- latio * would have done. //. Receptwm. The agreement by which shipmasters, innkeepers and stablemen {nautae, caupones, stabularii) under- took to take care of the goods or property of their customers was known as receptwm, and was enforced by means of an actio de recepto as rigorously as the duties of common carriers are enforced by the Common Law". The Edict was expressed as follows : navtae CAVPONES stabvlarii qvod cvivsqve salvvm fore RECEPERINT NISI RESTITVENT, IN EOS IVDICIVM DABO ; ' Bruns, loc. cit. J). 68. " 13 Dig. 5. 2. ' Bruns, ib. p. 69. < 13 Dig. 5. 28. ' Camazza, Dir. Com. p. 106. Digitized by Microsoft® THEORIES AS TO RECEPTVM. 215 and the remedy was an ordinary actio in factv/m, authorising the judge to assess damages for the loss or non-production of the goods. But the contract which more nearly concerns us is receptum argentariorum, the nature of which has been a subject of much controversy. This was a formless promise to pay on behalf of another man, and we gather from Justinian ' that it was capable of creating an original debt; capable of being made svb conditione or in diem, and en- forced by an actio recepticia, which was perpetua; while Theophilus tells us' that it was confined to bankers (argentarii). Bruns" indeed supposes that receptum was a formal contract iuris ciuilis, while according to Voigt* it was a species of expensilatio devised by the argentarii. Lenel^ however has proved that receptum argentariorum was introduced and regulated by the Praetor in the same part of the Edict in which he treated of the recepta nautarum, cauponarum and stabulariorum. This appears from the fact that in 13 Big. 5. 27 and 28, constituere has evidently been substituted by Tribonian and his colleagues for recipere. Ulpian treated of constitutwm in his 27th book on the Edict": but the passage quoted in the Digest is from his 14th book on the Edict, in which we know ' that he discussed the clause Nautae caupon^s sta- hularii. So also Pomponius, who discussed recepta 1 4 Cod. 18. 2. 2 IV. 6-8. » Z. fur RG. i. 51 ft. * fiSm. EG. I. 65-8. ' Z. der Sav. Stift. ii. 62 S. « 13 Dig. 5. 16. ' 4 Dig. 9. 1. Digitized by Microsoft® 216 CONTBACTS NOT CLASSIFIED. nautarvm, &c. in his 34th book^ and constitutum in his 8th*, is described' as mentioning the latter in his 34th book. Gains also is represented to have dealt with constitutum in the very same book* in which he treated of recepta nautarum^. We must conclude, either that all these writers introduced into their discussion of recepta naviarum &c. the totally irrelevant subject of constitutum, or that the subject thus introduced was not constitutum but receptum argentariorum. If the latter conclusion ' is correct, as we may well believe that it must be, it follows that receptum, argentariorum was, like the other recepta, regulated by the Praetorian Edict, and was therefore not a contract iuris ciuilis. By analogy with the other recepta we may further conclude that receptum argentariorum was formless, and hence cannot have been a species of eoopensilatio. The remedy was of course an actio in factum. Recipere is used by Cicero* in the sense of under- taking a personal guarantee, but with no clearly technical meaning. Justinian states that the ouctio recepticia was objectionable on account of its "solem- nia uerba," and Lenel has explained this to mean that the actio recepticia, being necessarily in factum like those of the other recepta, had to contain the words "si paret soluturwm recepisse. n^que soluisse quod solui recepit," of which recipere was a technical term. This term, being misunderstood by the Greeks, was translated in Justinian's time > 4 Dig. 9. 1 fr. 7 and 9. 3. ^ 13 Vig. 5. 5 fr. 5. » ib. 5. 27. * ib. 5. 28. = 4 Dig. 9. 2 and 5. « Phil. V. 18. 51. ; ad Fam. xiii. 17. Digitized by Microsoft® A MERCANTILE DEVICE. 217 by constitmre. It is almost certain that the actio recepticia was known before the end of the Republic, since Labeo evidently ' discussed it. The function of receptum probably was to provide an international mode of assigning indebtedness, because transcriptio a persona in persona/m was not available to peregrins'. The existence of the debt between the creditor and the original debtor was clearly not affected by the obligation of the argen- tarius who had made a receptum; and from the passages above cited Lenel also infers that receptum pro alio was the only known form which the contract ever took. In short, it seems to have closely resem- bled the acceptance of a modem bill of exchange", and it was doubtless made by the argentarius on behalf of his clients or correspondents. 1 13 Dig. 5. 27. ' Lenel, Z. der Sav. Stift. n. 70. 3 Carnazza, Dir. Com. p. 93. Digitized by Microsoft® CONCLUSION. We have now traced the development of the Roman Law of Contract from an early stage of Formalism, in which few agreements were actionable, and those few provided with imperfect remedies, to the almost complete maturity to which it had attained by the end of the Republia Of all the contracts which we have examined, nexum and uadimoniwn seem to be the only two that became obsolete during this period, while the new contracts of Praetorian origin, such as depositwm and constitutum, attained their full growth, as we have seen ; so that the jurists of the Empire found little to do besides the work of interpretation and amplification. The one great improvement, and almost the only one, which the Law of Contract underwent sub- sequently to our period, was the introduction of the actiones praescriptis uerhis, by which the scope of Real Contract was immensely enlarged. Li other respects, the Law of the Republic has the credit of having generated that wonderful- system of Contract which later ages have scarcely ever failed to copy, and which lies at the root of so much of English Law.
Tuesday, March 29, 2022
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment