The Grice Club

Welcome

The Grice Club

The club for all those whose members have no (other) club.

Is Grice the greatest philosopher that ever lived?

Search This Blog

Tuesday, April 19, 2022

GRICE E CODRONCHI: IL NESSO

 Whoever has glanced through the pages of  any text-book on Mercantile Law will hardly deny  that Contract is the handmaid if not actually the  child of Trade. Merchants and bankers must have  what soldiers and farmers seldom need, the means  of making and enforcing various agreements with  ease and certainty. Thus, turning to the special  case before us, we should expect to find that when  Rome was in her infancy and when her free  inhabitants busied themselves chiefly with tillage  and with petty warfare, their rules of sale, loan,  suretyship, were few and clumsy. Villages do not  contain lawyers, and even in tdwns hucksters do  not employ them. Poverty of Contract was in fact  a striking feature of the early Roman Law, and can  be readily understood in the light of the rule just  stated. The explanation given by Sir Henry Maine  is doubtless true, but does not seem altogether  adequate. He points out 1 that the Roman house-  hold consisted of many families under the rule of a   1 Ancient Law, p. 312.  B. E. 1     2 INTRODUCTION.   paternal autocrat, so that few freemen had what we  should call legal capacity, and consequently there  arose few occasions for Contract. This may indeed  account for the non-existence of Agency, but not  for that of all other contractual forms. For if the  households had been trading instead of farming  corporations, they must necessarily have been more  richly provided in this respect. The fact that their  commerce was trivial, if it existed at all, alone  accounts completely for the insignificance of Con-  tract in their early Law.   The origin of Contract as a feature of social life  was therefore simultaneous with the birth of Trade  and requires no further explanation. It is with the  origin and history of its individual forms that the  following pages have to deal. As Roman civilization  progresses we find Commerce extending and Contract  growing steadily to be more complex and more  flexible. Before the end of the Roman Republic  the rudimentary modes of agreement which sufficed  for the requirements of a semi-barbarous people  have been almost wholly transformed into the  elaborate system f of Contract preserved for us in  the fragments of the Antonine jurists.     CHAPTER I.   THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS.   At the most remote period concerning which  statements of reasonable accuracy can be made,  and which for convenience we may call the Regal  Period, we can distinguish three ways of securing  the fulfilment of a promise. The promise could  be enforced either (1) by the person interested,  or (2) by the gods, or (3) by the community. When  however we speak of enforcement, we must not think  of what is now called specific performance, a con-  ception unknown to primitive Law. The only kind  of enforcement then possible was to make punish-  ment the alternative of performance.   I. Self-help, the most obvious method of re-  dress in a society just emerging from barbarism, was  doubtless the most ancient protection to promises,  since we find it to have been not only the mode by  which the anger of the individual was expressed, but  also one of the authorised means employed by the  gods or the community to signify their displeasure.  This rough form of justice fell within the domain of  Law in the sense that the law allowed it, and even   1—2     4 THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS.   encouraged men to punish the delinquent, whenever  religion or custom had been violated. But as people  grew more civilized and the nation larger, self-help  must have proved a difficult and therefore inade-  quate remedy. Accordingly its scope was by degrees  narrowed, and at last with the introduction of surer  methods it became wholly obsolete.   II. Religious Law, as administered by the  priests, the representatives of the gods, was another  powerful agency for the support of promises. A  violation of Fides, the sacred bond formed between  the parties to an agreement, was an act of impiety  which laid a burden on the conscience of the delin-  quent and may even have entailed religious disabili-  ties. Fides was of the essence of every compact,  but there were certain cases in which its violation  was punished with exceptional severity. If an  agreement had been solemnly made in the presence  of the gods, its breach was punishable as an act  of gross sacrilege.   III. The third agency for the protection of  promises was legal in our sense of the word. It  consisted of penalties imposed upon bad faith by  the laws of the nation, the rules of the gens, or the  by-laws of the guild to which the delinquent  belonged. What the sanction was in each case we  are left to conjecture. It may have been public  disgrace, or exclusion from the guild, or the paying  of a fine. And as some promises might be strength-  ened by an appeal to the gods, so might others by  an invocation of the people as witnesses.   Agreements then might be of three kinds corre-     EARLY PACTA. 5   sponding to the three kinds of sanction. They  might consist of (1) an entirely formless compact,  (2) a solemn appeal to the gods, or (3) a solemn  appeal to the people.   I. A formless compact is called pactum in the  language of the twelve Tables. It was merely a  distinct understanding between parties who trusted  to each other's word, and in the infancy of Law  it must have been the kind of agreement most  generally used in the ordinary business of life.  Such agreements are doubtless the oldest of all,  since it is almost impossible to conceive of a time  when men did not barter acts and promises as freely  as they bartered goods and without the accompani-  ment of any ceremony. Compacts of this sort were  protected by the universal respect for Fides, and  their violation may perhaps have been visited with  penalties by the guild or by the gens. But intensely  religious as the early Romans were, there must have  been cases in which conscience was too weak a  barrier against fraud, and slight penalties were  ineffectual. Fear of the gods had to be reinforced  by the fear of man, and self-help was the remedy  which naturally suggested itself. In the twelve  Tables pactum appears in a negative shape,  as a compact by performing which retaliation or  a law-suit could be avoided 1 . If this compact was  broken the offended party pursued his remedy.  Similarly where a positive pactum was violated, the  injured person must have had the option of chastising   1 Gell. zx. 1. 14. Auct. ad Her. n. 13. 20.     6 THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS.   the delinquent. His revenge might take the form  of personal violence, seizure of the other's goods,  or the retention of a pawn already in his possession.  He could choose his own mode of punishment, but if  his adversary proved too strong for him, he doubtless  had to go unavenged ; whereas if the broken agree-  ment belonged to either of the other classes, the  injured party had the whole support of the  priesthood or the community at his back, and  thus was certain of obtaining satisfaction. It is  therefore plain that though formless agreements  contained the germ of Contract, they could not  have produced a true law of Contract, because by  their very nature they lacked binding force. Their  sanction depended on the caprice of individuals,  whereas the essence of Contract is that the breach  of an agreement is punishable in a particular way.  A further element was needed, and this was supplied  by the invocation of higher powers.   II. At what period the feshion was introduced  of confirming promises by an appeal to the gods  it would be idle to guess. Originally, it seems,  the plain meaning of such appeals was alone con-  sidered, and their form was of no importance.  But under the influence of custom or of the priest-  hood, they assumed by degrees a formal character,  and it is thus that we find them in our earliest  authorities.   Since Religion and Law were both at first the  monopoly of the priestly order, and since the religious  forms of promise have their counterpart in the  customs of Greece and other primitive peoples,     PUBLIC AGREEMENTS. 7   whereas the secular forms are peculiarly Roman 1 ,  the religious forms are evidently the older, and  formal contract has therefore had a religious origin.  Fides being a divine thing, the most natural means  of confirming a promise was to place it under divine  protection. This could be accomplished in two  ways, by iusiurandum or by sponsio, each of which  was a solemn declaration placing the promise or  agreement under the guardianship of the gods.  Each of these forms has a curious history, and as  they are the earliest specimens of true Contract,  we may discuss them in the next chapter.   III. Another method, and one peculiar to the  Romans, which naturally suggested itself for the  protection of agreements, was to perform the whole  transaction in view of the people. Publicity ensured  the fairness of the agreement, and placed its ex-  istence beyond dispute. If the transaction was  essentially a public matter, such as the official sale of  public lands, or the giving out of public contracts,  no formality seems ever to have been required, so  that even a formless agreement was in that case  binding. The same validity could be secured for  private contracts by having them publicly witnessed,  and the nexum was but one application of this  principle. In testamentary Law it seems probable  that the public will in comitiis calatis was also  formless, whereas in private the testator could only  give effect to his will by formally saying to his  fellow-citizens " testimonium mihi perhibetote"   Thus the two elements which turned a bare   1 See p. 22.     8 THE REGAL PERIOD: EARLY AGREEMENTS.   \ agreement into a contract were religion and publicity.  The naked agreements (pacta) need not concern us,  since their validity as contracts never received  complete recognition. But it will be the object of  the following pages to show how agreements grew  into contracts by being invested with a religious or  public dignity, and to trace the subsequent process  by which this outward clothing was slowly cast off.  Formalism was the only means by which Contract  could have risen to an established position, but  when that position was folly attained we shall find  Contract discarding forms and returning to the state  of bare agreement from which it had sprung.     CHAPTER II.   CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   Art 1. Ivsivrandvm is derived by some  from Iouisiurandum 1 , which merely indicates that  Jupiter was the god by whom men generally swore.  To make an oath was to call upon some god to  witness the integrity of the swearer, and to punish  him if he swerved from it. This appears from the  wording of the oath in Livy 2 , where Scipio says: "Si  sciensfalloy turn me, Iuppiter optime maxime, domum  familiam remque rneam pessimo leto afficias" and  from the oath upon the Iuppiter lapis given by  Polybius and Paulus Diaconus, where a man throws  down a flint and says : " Si sciens /alio, turn me  Dispiter salua urbe arceque bonis eiiciat, uti ego hunc  lapidem" A promise accompanied by an oath was  simply a unilateral contract under religious sanction.  And it would seem that the oath was in fact used for  purposes of contract. Cicero remarks 8 that the oath  was proved by the language of the XII Tables to  have been in former times the most binding form of  promise ; and since an oath was still morally binding   1 Cf. Apul. de deo Socr. 5. a xzii. 53.   » Off. ni. 31. 111.     10 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.,   in the time of Cicero, though it had then no legal  force, the point of his remark must be that in  earlier times the oath was legally binding also.  From Dionysius we know that the altar of Hercules  (called Ara Maxima) was a place at which solemn  compacts (ovvdfjtcai) were often made 1 , while Plautus  and Cicero inform us that such compacts were  solemnized by grasping the altar and taking an  oath 2 . It would seem probable that the gods were  consulted by the taking of auspices before an  oath was made. Cicero says that even in private  affairs the ancients used to take no step without  asking the advice of the gods 8 ; and we may safely  conjecture that whenever a god was called upon to  witness a solemn promise, he was first enquired of,  so that he might have the option of refusing his  assent by giving unfavourable auspices. The terms  of the oath were known as concepta uerba, at least  in the later Republic, and like the other forms of the  period they were strictly construed 4 . Periuriv/m did  not mean then, as now, false swearing. It meant  the breach of an oath 5 , the commission of any act at  variance with the uerha concepta 9 .   There is some dispute as to what were the exact  consequences of such a breach. Voigt 7 thinks that  it merely entailed excommunication from religious  rites, but Danz 8 is clearly right in maintaining that  its consequences in early times were far more serious ;   1 Dion. i. 40. 2 Plaut. Rud. 5. 2. 49. Cio. Flacc. 36. 90.   8 Div. 1. 16. 28. 4 Seru. ad Aen. 12. 13.   6 i.e. 8ciem fallere, Plin. Paneg. 64. Seneca, Ben. in. 37. 4.  6 Off. in. 29. 108. 7 Ius Nat. in. 229. 8 Ram. RG. n. § 149.     EFFECTS OF IVSIVRANDVM. 11   they amounted in fact to complete outlawry.  Cicero says that the sacratae leges of the ancients  confirmed the validity of oaths. Now a sacrata lex  was one which declared the transgressor to be  sacer (i.e. a victim devoted) to some particular god 1 ,  and sacer in the so-called laws of Seruius Tullius 2  and in the XII Tables 8 was the epithet of condem-  nation applied to the undutiful child and the  unrighteous patron. So likewise it seems highly  probable that the breaker of an oath became sacer,  and that his punishment, as Cicero hints 4 , was  usually death. The formula of an oath given by  Polybius 6 is more comprehensive than that given  by Paulus Diaconus 8 , for in it the swearer prays  that, if he should transgress, he may forfeit not  onry the religious but also the civil rights of his  countrymen. This shows that the oath-breaker was  an utter outcast; in fact, as the gods could not  always execute vengeance in person, what they did  was to withdraw their protection from the offender  and leave him tolhe punishment of his fellow-men 7 .  The drawbacks to this method of contract were the  same as those of the old English Law, which made  hanging the penalty for a slight theft ; the penalty  was likely to be out of all proportion to the injury  inflicted by a breach of the promise. So awful  indeed was it, that no promise of an ordinary kind  could well be given in such a dangerous form, and  consequently the oath was not available for the   1 Festus, p. 318, s.u. sacratae. 2 Fest. p. 230, s.u. plorare.   8 Seru. ad Aen. 6. 609. 4 Leg. n. 9. 22. B in. 25.   6 p. 114, s.u. lapidem. 7 Liu. v. 11. 16.     12 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   common affairs of daily life. The use of the oath  therefore disappeared with the rise of other forms of  binding agreement, the severity of whose remedies  was proportionate to the rights which had been  violated; while at the same time the breaking  of an oath came to be considered as a moral, instead  of a legal, offence, and by the end of the Republic  entailed nothing more serious than disgrace (dedecus).  In one instance only did the legal force of the oath  survive. As late as the days of Justinian^ the  services due to patrons by their freedmen were still  promised under oath 1 . But the penalty for the  neglect of those services had changed with the  development of the law. At and before the time of  the XII Tables, the freedman who neglected his  patron, like the patron who injured his freedman 2 ,  no doubt became sacer, and was an outlaw fleeing  for his life, as we are told by Dionysius 3 . But in  classical times the heavy religious penalty had  disappeared, and the iurisiurandi obligatio was en-  forced by a special praetorian action, the actio  operarum*. By the time of Ulpian the effects of  the iurata operarum promissio seem indeed to have  been identical with those of the operarum stipu-  latio*, though the forms of the two were still quite  distinct.   We may then summarise as follows our knowledge  as to this primitive mode of contract :   The form was a verbal declaration on the part of  the promisor, couched in a solemn and carefully   1 38 Dig. 1. 7. a Sera, ad Aen. 6. 609. 8 n. 10.   4 38 Dig. 1. 2 and 7. 5 Cf. 38 Dig. 1. 10.     1     THE EARLY 8P0N8I0. 13   worded 1 formula (concepta tierba), wherein he called  upon the gods {testari deos)*, to behold his good faith  and to punish him for a breach of it.   The sanction was the withdrawal of divine  protection, so that the delinquent was exposed to  death at the hand of any man who chose to slay  him.   The mode of release, if any, does not appear. In  classical times it was the acceptilatio*, but this Was  clearly anomalous and resulted from the similar  juristic treatment of operae promissae and operae  iuratae.   Art. 2. Sponsio. Though the point is contested  by high authority, yet it scarcely admits of a doubt  that there existed from very early times another  form, known as sponsio, by which agreements could  be made under religious sanction. This method,  as Danz has pointed out, was originally connected  with the preceding one. It was derived from the  stern and solemn compact made under an oath to  the gods. But Danz goes too far when he identifies  the two, and states that sponsio was but another  name for the sworn promise 4 . The stages through  which the sponsio seems to have passed tell a  different story. The word is closely connected with  airovSij, tnrivSeiv, and hence originally meant a  pouring out of wine 8 , quite distinct from the con-  vivial \ocfirf or libatio 6 , so that " libation " is not its  proper equivalent. The other derivation given by   1 38 Dig. 1. 7, fr. 3. 2 Plant. Rud. 5. 2. 52.   * 46 Dig. 4. 13. 4 Danz, Sacr. Schutz, p. 106.   8 Festus p. 329 s.u. spondere. 6 Leist, Greco-It. R. O. p. 464, note o.     14 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   Varro 1 and Verrius 2 from sports, the will, whence  according to Girtanner 8 sponsio must have meant a  declaration of the will, savours somewhat too strongly  of classical etymology.   I. This pouring out of wine, as Leist 4 has  shown, was in the Homeric age a constant accom-  paniment to the conclusion of a sworn compact of  alliance (optcia iriara) between friendly nations.  The sacrificial wine seems originally to have added  force to the oath by symbolising the blood which  would be spilt if the gods were insulted by a breach  of that oath. In this then its original form sponsio  was nothing more than an accessory piece of cere-  monial.   II. The second stage was brought about by the  omission of the oath and by the use of wine-pouring  alone as the principal ceremony in making less  important agreements of a private nature. In the  Indian Sutras for instance a sacrifice of wine is  customary at betrothals 5 , and comparison shows that  the marriage ceremonies of the Romans, in connec-  tion with which we find sponsio and sponsalia applied  to the betrothal and sponsa to the bride 6 , were very  like those of other Aryan communities 7 . We may  therefore clearly infer that at Rome also there was a  time when the pouring out of wine was a part of the  marriage-contract; and thus our derivation of the  word receives independent confirmation.   III. In the third and last stage sponsio meant   1 L. L. vi. 7. 69. 2 Festus, «. u. spondere. 8 Stip. p. 84.  4 Greco-It. B. G. § 60. 8 Leist, AlUAr. I. Civ. p. 448.   8 Gell. iv. 4. Varro, L. L. vi. 7. 70. 7 Leist, loc. ciu     PECULIAEITIES OF SPONSIO. 15   nothing more than a particular form of promise, and  it is easy to see how this came about. At first the  verbal promise took its name from the ceremony of  wine-pouring which gave to it binding force ; but in  course of time this ceremony was left out as taken  for granted, and then the promise alone, provided  words of style were correctly used, still retained its  old uses and its old name. Sponsio from being a  ceremonial act became a form of words. Such was  the final stage of its development.   The importance attached to the use of the words  spondesne ?, spondeo in preference to all others 1 thus  becomes clear. Spondesne ? spondeo originally meant  " Do you promise by the sacrifice of wine V "I do so  promise," just as we say, "I give you my oath,"  when we do not dream of actually taking one.   Another peculiarity of sponsio, noticed though  not explained by Gaius 2 , was the fact that it could  be used in one exceptional case to make a binding  agreement between Romans and aliens, namely, at  the conclusion of a treaty. Gaius expresses surprise  at this exception. But if, as above stated, a sacrifice  of pure wine {airovhal a/cprjTot) was one of the early  formalities of an international compact (op/cia mard),  it was natural that the word spondeo should survive  on such occasions, even after the oath and the wine-  pouring had long since vanished.   Sponsio being then a religious act and subse-  quently a religious formula, its sanctity was doubtless  protected by the pontiffs with suitable penalties.  What these penalties were we cannot hope to know,   1 Gai. in. 93. 2 in. 94.     16 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   though clearly they were the forerunners of the  penal sponsio tertiae partis of the later procedure.  Varro 1 informs us that, besides being used at be-  trothals the sponsio was employed in money (pecu/nia)  transactions. If pecunia includes more than money  we may well suppose that cattle and other forms of  property, which could be designated by number and  not by weight, were capable of being promised in  this manner. Indeed it is by no means unlikely 2  that nexum was at one time the proper form for  a loan of money by weight, while sponsio was the  proper form for a loan of coined money (pecunia  nwmerata). The making of a sponsio for a sum  of money was at all events the distinguishing feature  of the afibio per sponsionem, and though we cannot  now enter upon the disputed history of that action,  its antiquity will hardly be denied.   The account here given of the origin and early  history of the sponsio is so different from the views  taken by many excellent authorities that we must  examine their theories in order to see why they  appear untenable. One great class of commentators  have held that the sponsio is not a primitive institu-  tion, but was introduced at a date subsequent to the  XII Tables. The adherents of this theory are  afraid of admitting the existence, at so early a period,  of a form of contract so convenient and flexible  as the sponsio, and they also attach great weight to  the fact that no mention of sponsio occurs in our  fragments of the XII Tables. While it would  doubtless be an anachronism to ascribe to the early   1 L. L. vi. 7. 70. a Karsten, Stip. p. 42.     J     THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF SPONSIO. 17   sponsio the actionability and breadth of scope which  it had in later times, still it may very well have  been sanctioned by religious law, in ways of which  nothing can be known unless the pontifical Com-  mentaries of Papirius 1 should some day be discovered.  As to the silence of the XII Tables on this  subject, we are told by Pomponius that they were  intended to define and reform the law rather than  to serve as a comprehensive code 2 . Therefore they  may well have passed over a subject like sponsio  which was already regulated by the priesthood. Or,  if they did mention it, their provisions on the  subject may have been lost, like the provisions as to  iusiurandum, which' we know of only through a  casual remark of Cicero's 8 .   The early date here attributed to the sponsio  cannot therefore be disproved by any such negative  evidence. Let us see how the case stands with  regard to the question of origin.   (a) The theory best known in England, owing  to its support by Sir H. Maine, is that sponsio was a  simplified form of neocum, in which the ceremonial  had fallen away and the nuncupatio had alone been  left 4 . This explanation is now so utterly obsolete  that it is not worth refuting, especially since Mr  Hunter's exhaustive criticism 5 . One fact which in  itself is utterly fatal to such a theory is that the  nuncupatio was an assertion requiring no reply 6 ,   i Dion. in. 36. 2 1 Dig. 2. 2. 4.   8 Off. in. 31. 111. * Maine, Am. Law, p. 326.   5 Hunter, Roman Law, p. 385. 6 Gai. n. 24.   B. E. 2     18 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   whereas the essential thing about the sponsio was a  question coupled with an answer.   (6) Voigt follows Girtanner in maintaining that  spondere signified originally " to declare one's will,"  and he vaguely ascribes the use of sponsiones in  the making of agreements to an ancient custom  existing at Borne as well as in Latium 1 . He agrees  with the view here expressed that the sponsio was  known prior to the XII Tables, but thinks that  before the XII Tables it was neither a contract  (which is strictly true if by contract we mean an  agreement enforceable by action), nor an act in the  law, and that its use as a contract began in the  fourth century as a result of Latin influence 2 . In  another place 8 he expresses the opinion that its  introduction as a contract was due to legislation, and  most probably to the Lex Silia. The objections to  this view are (1) that the etymology is probably  wrong, and (2) that the inference drawn as to the  original meaning of spondere iuvolves us in serious  difficulties. An expression of the will can be made  by a formless declaration as well as by a formal one.  And if a formless agreement be a sponsio, as it must  be if sponsio means any declaration of the will,  how are we to explain the formal importance  attaching to the use of the particular words " spon-  desne ? spondeo." (3) This view ignores the religious  nature of the sponsio, which I have endeavoured to  establish, and (4) it forgets that sponsio, being part  of the marriage ceremonial, one of the first subjects   1 Rom. RG. i. p. 42. 2 16. p. 43.   8 Ius Nat. §§ 33-4.     THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF SPONSIO* 19   to be regulated by the laws of Romulus 1 , is most  probably one of the oldest Roman institutions.  Again (5), as Esmarch has observed 2 , the legislative  origin of the sponsio is a very rash hypothesis. We  only know that the Lex Silia introduced an improved  procedure for matters which were already actionable,  and had a new formal contract been created by such  a definite act we should almost certainly have been  informed of this by the classical writers.   (c) Danz also derives sponsio from sports, the  will; but he takes spondere to mean sua sponte  iurare, and thinks that the original sponsio was  exactly the same as iusiurandum, i.e. nothing more  than an oath of a particular kind 3 . . His chief argu-  ment for this view is to be found in Paulus Diaconus,  who gives consponsor = coniurator. But why need  we suppose that Paulus meant more than to give a  synonym ? in which case it by no means follows that  spondere = iurare. For such a statement as that we  have absolutely no authority. Moreover, as we saw  above, iusiurandum was a one-sided declaration on  the part of the promisor only. How then could the  sponsio, consisting as it did of question and answer,  have sprung from such a source ? especially since  the iusiurandum, though no longer armed with  a legal sanction, was still used as late as the days of  Plautus alongside of the sponsio and in complete  contrast to it ?   (d) Girtanner, in his reply to the "Sacrale  Schutz" of Danz 4 , maintains that sponsio had nothing   1 Dion. n. 25. 2 K. V. filr G. u. R. W. n. 516.   3 Sacr. Schutz, p. 149. 4 Ueber die Sponsio, p. 4 fif.   2—2     9   20 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   to do with an oath, but was a simple declaration of  the individual will, and that stipulatio had its origin  in the respect paid to Fides. This view however  is even less supported by evidence than that of  Danz 1 . Arguing again from analogy Girtanner  thinks that, as the Roman people regulated its  affairs by expressing its will publicly in the Comitia,  so we may conjecture that individuals could validly  express their will in private affairs, in other words  could make a binding sponsio. But this, as well  as being a wrong analogy, is a misapprehension of a  leading principle of early Law. For, as we have  seen, no agreement resting simply upon the will of  the parties (i.e. pactum) was valid without some  outward stamp being affixed to it, in the shape  of approval expressed by the gods or by the people.  In the language of the more modern law, we may  say that such approval, tacit or explicit, religious or  secular, was the original causa ciuilis which dis-  tinguished contractus from pactiones. Now a popular  vote in the Comitia bore the stamp of public  approval as plainly as did the nexum. But the  sponsio, requiring no witnesses, was clearly not  endorsed by the people ; therefore the endorsement  which it needed in order to become a contractus  iuris cvuilis must have been of a religious nature,  and that such was the case appears plainly if we  admit that sponsio originated in a religious cere-  monial such as I have described.   To recapitulate the view here given, we may  conclude that sponsio was a primordial institution   1 See Windscheid, K. F. fiir G. «. R. W. i. 291.     GROWTH OF SPONSIO. 21   of the Roman and Latin peoples, which grew into its  later form through three stages, (a) It was originally  a sacrifice of wine annexed to a solemn compact of  alliance or of peace made under an oath to the gods.  (b) Next it became a sacrifice used as an appeal to  the gods in compacts not made under oath such as  betrothals. Just as iusiurandum for many purposes  was sufficient without the pouring out of wine, so for  other purposes sponsio came to be sufficient without  the oath, (c) Lastly it became a verbal formula,  expressed in language implying the accompaniment  of a wine-sacrifice, but at the making of which no  sacrifice was ever actually performed. In this final  stage, which continued as late as the days of Justi-  nian,   Its form was a question put by the promisee,  and an answer given by the promisor, each using  the verb spondere. " Filiam mihi spondesne ? "  " Spondeo? " Centum dari spondes ? " " Spondeo?  Throughout its history this was a form which Roman  citizens alone could use, in which fact we clearly see  religious exclusiveness and a further proof of religious  origin. Why they used question and answer rather  than plain statement is a minor point the origin  of which no theory has yet accounted for. The  most plausible conjecture seems to be that the  recapitulation by the promisee was intended to  secure the complete understanding by the promisor  of the exact nature of his promise.   Its sanction in the early period of which we  are treating was doubtless* imposed by the priests,  but owing to our almost complete ignorance of the     22 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   pontifical law we cannot tell what that sanction  was.   Having now examined the ways in which an  agreement could be made binding under religious  sanction, let us see how binding agreements could  be made with the approval of the community.  There is reason to believe that this secular class  of contracts is less ancient than the religious class,  because nexum and mancipium were peculiar to the  Romans, whereas traces of iusiurandum and sponsio  are found, as Leist has shown, in other Aryan  civilizations 1 .   Art. 3. nexvm. There is no more disputed sub-  ject in the whole history of Roman Law than the  origin and development of this one contract. Yet the  facts are simple, and though we cannot be sure that  every detail is accurate, we have enough information  to see clearly what the transaction was like as  a whole. We know that it was a negotium per aes  et libram, a weighing of raw copper or other  commodity measured by weight in the presence of  witnesses 2 ; that the commodity so weighed was  a loan 8 ; and that default in the repayment of a loan  thus made exposed the borrower to bondage 4 and  savage punishment at the hands of the lender. We  know also that it existed as a loan before the XII  Tables, for it is mentioned in them as something  quite different from mancipium 6 . To assert, as Bech-  mann does, that since nexum included conveyance as   1 Alt Ar. I. Civ. I« e Abt. pp. 435-443.   2 Gai. in. 173. 3 Muciu* in Varro, L. L. 7. 105.  4 Varro, L. L. vi. 5. 5 Clark, E. R. L. § 22.     THEORIES AS TO ORIGIN OF NEXVM. 23   well as loan " mancipiumque " must therefore be an  interpolation into the text of the XII Tables 1 , is an  arbitrary and unnecessary conjecture. The etymology  of nexwm, and of mancipium shows that they were  distinct conceptions. Mancipium implies the transfer  of mami8, ownership ; nexum implies the making of  a bond (cf. nectere, to bind), the precise equivalent  of obligatio in the later law. It is true that both  nexwm and mancipium required the use of copper  and scales, to measure in one case the price, in the  other the amount of the loan. But this coincidence  by no means proves that the two transactions were  identical. A modern deed is used both for leases and  for conveyances of real property, yet that would be  a strange argument to prove that a lease and a  conveyance were originally the same thing. Here  however we are met by a difficulty. If, as some  hold 8 and as I have tried to prove, we must regard  mancipium as an institution of prehistoric times  distinct from the purely contractual nexwm, how  are we to explain the fact that nexwm is used  by Cicero 8 and by other classical writers 4 as equi-  valent to mancipium, or as a general term signifying  omne quod per aes et libram geritur, whether a loan,  a will, or a conveyance ? Now first we must notice  the fact that neamm had at any rate not always been  synonymous with mancipium, for if it had been so,  there could have been no doubt in the minds of   1 Kauf f p. 130. * Mommsen, Hist. 1. 11. p. 162 n.   * ad Fam. 7. 30 ; de Or. 3. 40; Top. 5. 28; Parad. 5. 1. 35. ; pro  Mwr. 2.   4 Boethius lib. 3 ad Top. 5. 28 ; Gallus Aelius in Festas, s.u.  nexwm ; Manilim in Varro, L. L. 7. 105.     24 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   Scaeuola and Varro that a res nexa was the same  thing as a res mamipata. This Scaeuola and Varro  both deny, and we must remember that Mucius  Scaeuola was the Papinian of his day. Manilius 1 on  the other hand, struck perhaps by the likeness in  form of the obsolete nexum to other still existing  negotia per aes et libram, seems to have made nexum  into a generic term for this whole class of trans-  actions. In this he was followed by Gallus Aelius 2 .  The new and wider meaning, given by them to that  which was a technical term at the period of the  XII Tables, apparently became general in literature,  partly for the very reason that nexum no longer had  an actual existence, partly because need liberatio,  the old release of nexum, had been adopted by  custom as the proper form of release in matters  which had nothing to do with the original nexum,  namely in the release of judgment-debts and of  legacies per damnationem*. One peculiarity men-  tioned by Gaius in the release of such legacies  seems altogether fatal to the theory that mandpium  was but a species of the genus nexum. Gaius says  that nexi liberatio could be used only for legacies of  things measured by weight. Such things were the  sole objects of the true nexum, whereas res maricipi  included land and cattle. Therefore if mancipiwm  were only a species of nexum we should certainly  find nexi liberatio applying to legacies of res mancipi,  but this, as Gaius shows, was not the case.   The view that nexum was the parent gestum per   1 Varro, L. L. vu. 105. a Festus, p. 165, s. u. nexum.   3 Gai. iii. 173-5.     NEXVM DISTINCT FROM MANCIPIVM. 25   aes et libram, and that mancipium was the name  given later to one particular form of nexum, is worth  examining at some length, because it is widely  accepted 1 , and because it fundamentally affects our  opinion concerning the early history of an important  contract. Bechmarm 2 thinks it more reasonable to  suppose that nexum narrowed from a general to a  specific conception. But it is scarcely conceivable  that nexum should have had the vague generic  meaning of quodcumque per aes et libram geritur*  when it was still a living mode of contract, and the  technical meaning of obligatio per aes et libram  when such a contractual form no longer existed.  What seems far more likely is that nexum had a  technical meaning until it ceased to be practised  subsequently to the Lex Poetilia, and that its loose  meaning was introduced in the later Bepublic, partly  to denote the binding force of any contract 4 , partly  as a convenient expression for any transaction per  aes et libram\ Even in Cicero we find the word  nexum used chiefly with a view to elegance of style 8  in places where mandpatio would have been a  clumsy word and where 7 there could be no doubt as  to the real meaning. But when Cicero is writing  history, he uses nexum in its old technical sense and  actually tells us that it had become obsolete 8 .   1 See Bechmann, Kauf, i. p. 130 ; Clark, E. R. L. § 22.   2 .16. p. 181. • Varro, I. c. — Festus, *. u. nexum.   4 Cf. "nexu uetu&ti " in Ulpian, 12 Dig. 6. 26. 7.   5 Cic. de Or. in. 40. 159.   6 Uar. Resp. vn. 14; ad Fam. vii. 30. 2; Top. 5. 28.   7 As in pro Mur. 2; Parad. v. 1. 35.   8 de Rep. 2. 34 and cf. Liu. mi. 28. 1.     26 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   Rejecting then as untenable the notion that  nexum denoted a variety of transactions, let us  see how it originated. The most obvious way of  lending corn or copper or any other ponderable  commodity, was to weigh it out to the borrower,  who would naturally at the same time specify by  word of mouth the terms on which he accepted  the loan. In order to make the transaction binding,  an obvious precaution would be to call in witnesses,  or if the transaction took place, as it most likely  would, in the market-place, the mere publicity of the  loan would be enough. Thus it was, we may  believe, that a nexurn was originally made. It was  a formless agreement necessarily accompanied by  the act of weighing and made under public super-  vision. It dealt only with commodities which could  be measured with the scales and weights, and did  not recognize the distinction between res mancipi  and res nee mancipi, — a strong argument that  nescum and mandpium were, as above said, totally  distinct affairs. Its sanction lay in the acts of  violence which the creditor might see fit to commit  against the debtor, if payment was not performed  according to the terms of his agreement. Personal  violence was regulated by the XII Tables, in the  rules of manus iniectio, but before that time it is safe  to conjecture that any form of retaliation against the  person or property of the debtor was freely allowed.   The fixing of the number of witnesses at five 1 ,  which we find also in rnancipium, . is the only  modification of nexum that we know of prior to   1 Gai. hi. 174.     . FUNCTION OF NEXAL WITNESSES. 27   the XII Tables. Bekker 1 suggests that this change  was one of the reforms of Seruius Tullius, and that  the five witnesses, by representing the five classes of  the Servian ceruma, personified the whole people.  This is a mere conjecture, but a very plausible one.  For we are told by Dionysius 8 that Seruius made  fifty enactments on the subject of Contract and  Crime, and in another passage of the same author 8 ,  we find an analogous case of a law which forbade the  exposure of a child except with the approval of five  witnesses. But here a question has been raised as to  what the witnesses did. The correct answer, I  believe, is that given by Bechmann 4 , who maintains  that the witnesses approved the transaction as a  whole, and vouched for its being properly and fairly  performed. Huschke, on the other hand, claims that  the function of the witnesses was to superintend the  weighing of the copper, and that before the intro-  duction of coined money some such public supervision  was necessary in order to convert the raw copper  into a lawful medium of exchange 5 . This view  is part of Huschke's theory, that neacum had two  marked peculiarities: (1) it was a legal act per-  formed under public authority, and (2) it was the  recognised mode of measuring out copper money by  weight.   The first part of Huschke's theory may be  accepted without reserve, but the second part seems  quite untenable. We have no evidence to show  that nexum was confined to loans of money or of   1 Akt, i. 22 ff. a iv. 13. » ii. 15.   4 Kauf, i. p. 90. 8 Nexum, p. 16 ff.     28 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   copper. Indeed we gather from a passage of Cicero  that far, corn, may have been the earliest object of  nexum 1 , while Gaius states that anything measurable  by weight could be dealt with by neari solvtio*. No  inference in favour of Huschke's theory can be  drawn from the name negotium per cms et libram,  for this phrase obviously dates from the more recent  times when the ceremony had only a formal signifi-  cance, and when the aes (ravduscvlum) was merely  struck against the scales. If then we reject the  second part of Huschke's theory, and admit, as  we certainly should, that nexum could deal with any  ponderable commodity, it is evident that his whole  view as to the function of the witnesses must  collapse also. The very notion of turning copper  from merchandise into legal tender is far too subtle  to have ever occurred to the minds of the early  Romans. As Bechmann 8 rightly remarks, the  original object of the State in making coin was  not to create an authorised medium of exchange,  but simply to warrant the weight and fineness of  the medium most generally used. The view of  Buschke seems therefore a complete anachronism.  There is also another interpretation of neawm  radically different from the one here advocated, and  formerly given by some authorities 4 , but which  has few if any supporters among modern jurists.  This , view was founded upon a loosely expressed  remark of Varro's in which nexus is defined as   1 Cic. de Leg. Agr. n. 30. 83. 2 in. 175. 8 Kauf, i. p. 87.  4 See Sell, Scbeurl, Niebuhr, Christiansen, Puchta, quoted in  Danz, Rom. RG. n. 25.     NEXVM A LOAN BY WEIGHT. 29   a freeman who gives himself into slavery for a debt  which he owes 1 . The inference drawn from this  remark was that the debtor's body, not the creditor's  money, was the object of nexwm, and that a debtor  who sold himself by mancipium as a pledge for the  repayment of a loan was said to make a nexum' 2 .  Such a theory does not however harmonize with the  facts. The evidence is entirely opposed to it, for  Varro's statement, as will be seen later on, admits of  quite another meaning. Neither nexum nor man-  cipium is ever found practised by a man upon  his own person. Nor could nexum have applied to a  debtors person, for the idea of treating a debtor like  a res mancipi or like a thing quod pondere numero  constat, is absurd. Again, if nexum = mancipium, the  conveyance of the debtors body as a pledge must  have taken effect as soon as the money was lent,  therefore (1) by thus becoming nexus he must have  been in mancipio long before a default could occur,  which is too strange to be believed, and (2) being in  mancipio he must have been capite deminutus*, which  Quintilian expressly states that no nexal debtor ever  was 4 . Clearly then mancipium was under no cir-  cumstances a factor in nexum.   Thus it would seem that the theory which  regards nexum as a loan of raw copper or other goods  measurable by weight, is the one beset with fewest  difficulties. Such goods correspond pretty nearly  to what in the later law were called res fungibiles.   1 Varro, L. L. vii. 105 and see page 52.   8 nexum inire, Liu. vn. 19. 6.   3 Paul. Diao. p. 70, *. u. deminutus. 4 Decl. 311.     30 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   The borrower was not required to return the very  same thing, but an equal quantity of the same kind  of thing. And this explains why neanim, the first  genuine contract of the Roman Law, should have  received such ample protection. A tool or a beast of  burden could be lent with but little risk, for either  could be easily identified ; but the loan of corn or of  metal would have been attended with very great  risk, had not the law been careful to ensure the  publicity of every such transaction. lusiurandum  or sponsio might no doubt have been used for  making loans, but they both lacked . the great  advantage of accurate measurement, which neanim  owed to its public character. It was the presence of  witnesses which raised neanim from a formless loan  into a contract of loan.   This general sketch of the original neanim is  all that can be given with certainty. The details  of the picture cannot be filled in, unless we draw  upon our imagination. We do not know what verbal  agreement passed between the borrower and the  lender, though it is fairly certain that payment  of interest on the loan might be made a part of the  contract. We cannot even be quite sure whether the  scale-holder (libripens) was an official, as some have  suggested, or a mere assistant 1 .   Our description of the contract may then be  briefly recapitulated as follows:   The form consisted of the weighing out and  delivery to the borrower of goods measurable by  weight, in the presence of witnesses, (five in number,   1 See page 52.     EARLY FORM OF NEXVM. 31   probably since the time of Seruius Tullius), whose  attendance ensured the proper performance of the  ceremony. The ownership of the particular goods  passed to the borrower, who was merely bound to  return an equal quantity of the same kind of goods,  but the terms of each contract were approximately  fixed by a verbal agreement uttered at the time.   The sanction consisted of the violent measures  which the creditor might choose to take against a  defaulting debtor. Before the XII Tables there  seems to have been no limit to the creditor's power  of punishment. Any violence against the debtor  was approved by custom and justified by the noto-  riety of the transaction, so that self-help was more  easily exercised and probably more severe in the case  of nexum than in that of any other agreement.   The release (nexi solutio) was a ceremony pre-  cisely similar to that of the nexum itself, the amount  of the loan being weighed and delivered to the lender,  in presence of witnesses 1 .   Art. 4. We have now examined three methods  by which a binding promise could be made in the  earliest period of the Roman Law. The next  question which confronts us is whether there existed  at that time any other method. The other forms of  contract, besides those already described, which are  found existing at the period of the XII Tables, were  fiducia, lex mancipi, uadimonium, and dotis dictio.  Did any of these have their origin before this time ?  Fiducia is doubtful, and lex mancipi, as we shall  see, owed its existence to an important provision   1 Gai. in. 174.     \.t     32 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   of that code. As to the origin of uadirnonium,  we cannot be certain, but judging from a passage  in Gellius 1 we are almost forced to the conclusion  that uadimonium also was a creation of the XII  Tables. Gellius speaks of •' uades et subuades et XX V  asses et taliones...omnisque ilia XII Tabhlarum  antiquitas." We know that twenty-five asses was the  fine imposed by the XII Tables for cutting down  another man's tree, therefore it would seem from the  context that uades had also been introduced by that  code. The point cannot be settled, but since the  XII Tables were at any rate the first enactments  on the subject of which anything is known, we may  discuss uadimonium in treating of the next period.  The only contract of which the remote antiquity is  beyond dispute is the dotis dictio.   Art. 5. DOTIS DICTIO. Dionysius 8 informs us  that in the earliest times a dowry was given with  daughters on their marriage, and that if the father  could not afford this expense his clients were bound  to contribute. Hence it is clear not only that dos  existed from very early times, but that custom even  in remote antiquity had fenced it about with strict  rules. From Ulpian 8 we know that dos could be  bestowed either by dotis dictio, dotis promissio, or  dotis datio. The promissio was a promise by stipu-  lation, and the datio was the transfer by mancipation  or tradition of the property constituting the dowry ;  so that these two are easy to understand. But dotis  dictio is an obscure subject. It is difficult to know  whence it acquired its binding force as a contract,   1 xvi. 10. 8. 2 ii. 10. 8 Reg. vi. 1.     THEORIES A8 TO D0TI8 DICTIO. 33   since in form it was unlike all other contracts  with which we are acquainted. Its antiquity is  evidenced not only by this peculiarity of form, but  9,lso by a passage in the Theodosian Code which  speaks of dotis dictio as conforming with the ancient  law 1 . An illustration occurs in Terence 2 , where the  father says, "Dos, Pamphile, est decern talenta"  and Pamphilus, the future son-in-law, replies,  "Accipio"; but we need not conclude that the  transaction was always formal, for the above Code 8 ,  in permitting the use of any form, seems rather  to be restating the old law than making a new  enactment. A further peculiarity, stated by Ulpian 4  and by Gaius 5 , was that dotis dictio could be validly  used only by the bride, by her father or cognates on  the fathers side, or by a debtor of the bride acting  with her authority. Dictio is a significant word, for  Ulpian 6 distinguishes between dictum and promis-  sum, the former, he says, being a mere statement,  the latter a binding promise. This distinction should  doubtless be applied in the present case, since dotis  dictio and dotis promissio were clearly different.  The following theories seem to be erroneous :  (a) Von Meykow 7 holds that dictio was adopted  as a form of promise instead of sponsio for this family  affair of dos, in order not to hurt the feelings of the  bride and of her kinsmen by appearing to question  their bona fides. That theory would be a plausible  explanation, if dictio could ever have meant a   1 C. Th. 3. 12. 3. 2 And. 5. 4. 48. 3 3. 13. 4.   4 Reg. vi. 2. 5 Epit. n. 9. 3. 6 21 Dig. 1. 19.   7 Diet. d. Rfim. Brautg. p. 5 ff.   B. E. 3     34 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   promise, but from what Ulpian says, this can hardly  be admitted.   (6) Bechmann 1 , again, connects dotis dictio with  the ceremony of sponsio at the betrothal of a daughter.  The dos, he thinks, was promised by a sponsio made  at the betrothal, so that the peculiar form known as  dotis dictio was originally nothing more than the  specification of a dowry already promised. The dotis  dictio would therefore have been at first a mere  pactum adiectum, which was made actionable in  later times, while still preserving its ancient form.  The objection to this theory is tKat it lacks evidence :  indeed the only passage (that of Terence) in which  dotis dictio is presented to us with a context goes to  show that this contract was in no way connected  with the act of betrothal.   (c) Another explanation is given by Czylharz 2 ,  ie. that dotis dictio was a formal contract. His  view is based on the scholia attached to the  passage of Terence, which say of the bridegroom's  answer: "Mle nisi dixisset ' accipio' dos non esset."  Czylharz therefore looks upon the contract as an  inverted stipulation. The offer of a promise was  made by the promisor, and when accepted by the  promisee became a contract. Though such a process  is quite in harmony with modern notions of Contract,  it would have been a complete anomaly at Rome.  And we cannot believe that, if acceptance by the  promisee had been a necessary part of the dotis  dictio, we should not have been so informed by  Gaius, when he has been so careful to impress   1 Rom. Dotalrecht. 2 Abt. p. 103. a Z.f. R. G. vn. 243.     THEORY OF DANZ. 35   upon us that the dotis dictio could be made nulla  interrogatione praecedente. Thus the view of  Czylharz besides being in itself improbable is  almost entirely unsupported by evidence. Even the  scholiast on Terence need not necessarily mean that  " accipio " was an indispensable part of the trans-  action. He may merely have meant that the bride-  groom at this juncture could decline the proffered  dos if he chose, and this interpretation is borne out  by Iulianus 1 and Marcellus 8 , who give formulae  of dotis dictio without any words of acceptance.   A satisfactory solution of the problem seems  to have been found by Danz 8 . He looks upon  dos as having been due from the father or male  ascendants of the bride as an officium pietatis 4 ,  and quotes passages from the classical writers in  which they speak of refusing to dower a sister  or a daughter as a most shameful thing 5 . The  source of the obligation lay in this relationship  to the bride, not in any binding effect of the dotis  dictio itself. But in order that the obligation might  be actionable its amount had to be fixed, and this  was just what the dictio accomplished. It was an  acknowledgment of the debt which custom had  decreed that the bride's family must pay to the  bridegroom. In this respect the dos was precisely  analogous to the debt of service which a freedman  owed as an offidum to his patron, and which he  acknowledged by the iurata operarumpromissio. The  dos and the operae were both officio, pietatis, but   1 23 Dig. 3. 44. 2 23 Dig. 3. 59. 3 Rom. RO. I. 163.   4 See 23 Dig. 3. 2. 5 Plaut. Trin. 3. 2. 63 ; Oic. Quint. 31. 98.   3—2     36 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   it became customary to specify their nature and  their quantity. In the one case this was done by an  oath, in the other by a simple declaration, and in  both cases the law gave an action to protect these  anomalous forms of agreement. What kind of  action could be brought on a dotis dictio is not  known. Voigt 1 states it to have been an actio  dictae dotis, for which he even gives the formula,  but formula and action are alike purely conjectural.  We can only infer that the dotis dictio was action-  able since it constituted a valid contract. How or  when this came to pass we cannot tell.   A further advantage of Danz' theory, and one not  mentioned by him, is that it explains the capacity  of the three classes of persons by whom alone dotis  dictio could be performed. (1) The father and male  ascendants of the bride were bound to provide a dos  under penalty of ignominia 2 ; (2) the bride, if sui  iuris, was bound to contribute to the support of her  husband's household for exactly the same reason 3 ;  and (3) a debtor of the bride was bound to carry  out her orders with respect to her assets in his posses-  sion, and supposing her whole fortune to have con-  sisted of a debt due to her, it is evident that  a dotis dictio by the debtor was the only way in  which this fortune could be settled as a dos at all.  Thus the hypothesis that the dos was a debt  morally due from the father of the bride, or from  the bride herself, whenever a marriage took place,  completely explains the curious limitation with   1 XII Taf. ii. § 123. 2 24 Dig. 3. 1. 8 Cic. Top. 4. 23.     FORM OF D0TI8 DICTIO. 37   regard to the parties who could perform dotis  dictio. The nature of the transaction may then be  summarized as follows :   Its form was an oral declaration on the part  of (1) the bride's father or male cognates, (2) of the  bride herself, or (3) of a debtor of the bride, setting  forth the nature and amount of the property which  he or she meant to bestow as dowry, and spoken  in the presence of the bridegroom. Land as well as  moveables could be settled in this manner 1 . No  particular formula was necessary. The bridegroom  might, if he liked, express himself satisfied with the  dos so specified ; but his acceptance does not seem  to have been an essential feature of the proceeding.  Most probably he did not have to speak at all.   Its sanction does not appear, though we may be  sure that there was some action to compel perform-  ance of the promise. This action, whatever it may  have been, could of course be brought by the bride's  husband against the maker of the dotis dictio.  Perhaps in the earliest times the sanction was a  purely religious one.   Art. 6. Now that we have seen the various  ways in which a binding contract could be made in  the earliest period of Roman history, we may con-  sider briefly the general characteristics of that primi-  tive contractual system. The first striking point  is that all the contracts hitherto mentioned are  unilateral: the promisor alone was bound, and he  was not entitled, in virtue of the contract, to  any counterperformance on the part of the promisee.   1 Gai. Ep. 3. 9.     38 CONTRACTS OF THE REGAL PERIOD.   The second point is that the consent of the parties  was not sufficient to bind them. Over and above  that consent the agreement between them was  required to bear the stamp of popular or divine  approval. Even in dotis dictio, as we have just seen,  a simple declaration uttered by the promisor was  invested with the force of a contract merely because  the substance of that declaration was a transfer of  property approved and required by public opinion.  Thirdly we notice that the intention of the con-  tracting parties was verbally expressed, but that the  language employed was not originally of any impor-  tance (except in the one case of sponsio), provided the  intention was clearly conveyed. We must therefore  modify the statement so commonly made that the  earliest known contracts were couched in a particular  form of words. For how did each of these particular  forms originate and acquire the shape in which  we afterwards find it ? By having long been used  to express agreements which were binding though  their language was informal, and by having thus  gradually obtained a technical significance. Conse-  quently the formal stage was not the earliest stage  of Contract. The most primitive contract of all was  not an agreement clothed with a form, but an agree-  ment clothed with the approval of Church or  State.

No comments:

Post a Comment